FUTURE TRENDS IN HOUSING TENURE AND THE
ADEQUACY OF RETIREMENT INCOME
RACHEL SLAYMAKER, BARRA ROANTREE, ANNE NOLAN AND
CONOR O'TOOLE
RESEARCH
SERIES
NUMBER 143
JULY 2022
E
V
I
D
E
N
C
E
F
O
R
P
O
L
I
C
Y
FUTURE TRENDS IN HOUSING TENURE AND THE
ADEQUACY OF RETIREMENT INCOME
Rachel Slaymaker
Barra Roantree
Anne Nolan
Conor OToole
JULY 2022
RESEARCH SERIES
NUMBER 143
Available to download from www.esri.ie
The Economic and Social Research Institute
Whitaker Square, Sir John Rogersons Quay, Dublin 2
https://doi.org/10.26504/rs143
This Open Access work is licensed under a Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License
(https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and
reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly credited.
ABOUT THE ESRI
The mission of the Economic and Social Research Institute is to advance evidence-
based policymaking that supports economic sustainability and social progress in
Ireland. ESRI researchers apply the highest standards of academic excellence to
challenges facing policymakers, focusing on 12 areas of critical importance to 21st
Century Ireland.
The Institute was founded in 1960 by a group of senior civil servants led by
Dr T.K. Whitaker, who identified the need for independent and in-depth research
analysis to provide a robust evidence base for policymaking in Ireland.
Since then, the Institute has remained committed to independent research and its
work is free of any expressed ideology or political position. The Institute publishes
all research reaching the appropriate academic standard, irrespective of its
findings or who funds the research.
The quality of its research output is guaranteed by a rigorous peer review process.
ESRI researchers are experts in their fields and are committed to producing work
that meets the highest academic standards and practices.
The work of the Institute is disseminated widely in books, journal articles and
reports. ESRI publications are available to download, free of charge, from its
website. Additionally, ESRI staff communicate research findings at regular
conferences and seminars.
The ESRI is a company limited by guarantee, answerable to its members and
governed by a Council, comprising 14 members who represent a cross-section of
ESRI members from academia, civil services, state agencies, businesses and civil
society. The Institute receives an annual grant-in-aid from the Department of
Public Expenditure and Reform to support the scientific and public interest
elements of the Institutes activities; the grant accounted for an average of 30 per
cent of the Institutes income over the lifetime of the last Research Strategy. The
remaining funding comes from research programmes supported by government
departments and agencies, public bodies and competitive research programmes.
Further information is available at www.esri.ie
THE AUTHORS
Rachel Slaymaker and Barra Roantree are Research Officers at the Economic and
Social Research Institute (ESRI). Anne Nolan and Conor OToole are Associate
Research Professors at the ESRI. All hold adjunct positions at Trinity College Dublin
(TCD).
ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS
The research was funded by the Pensions Council under a Research Programme on
Housing and Pensions. The authors thank the Central Statistics Office (CSO) for
access to Survey on Income and Living Conditions (SILC) microdata, and the Irish
Longitudinal Study on Ageing (TILDA) for access to the TILDA microdata. Thanks
also to the members of the Pensions Council, and to the members of the Research
Programme Steering Committee (Ciaran Diamond, Des Henry, Brendan Kennedy,
Munro ODwyer) for helpful comments and guidance throughout the period of this
research programme. We are grateful to participants at an ESRI lunchtime seminar,
and to the external and internal reviewers for helpful comments. All views, errors
and omissions remain the sole responsibility of the authors.
This report has been accepted for publication by the Institute, which does not itself take institutional
policy positions. All ESRI Research Series reports are peer reviewed prior to publication. The authors
are solely responsible for the content and the views expressed.
Table of contents | v
TABLE OF CONTENTS
ABBREVIATIONS .................................................................................................................................. VII
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY ......................................................................................................................... IX
CHAPTER 1 INTRODUCTION ................................................................................................................ 1
1.1 Context ................................................................................................................ 1
1.2 Existing evidence ................................................................................................. 3
1.3 Contribution and report structure....................................................................... 7
CHAPTER 2 POLICY CONTEXT .............................................................................................................. 9
2.1 The Irish pension system ..................................................................................... 9
2.2 The Irish housing market ................................................................................... 11
CHAPTER 3 HOUSING TENURE AND COST SCENARIOS ..................................................................... 15
3.1 Housing tenure .................................................................................................. 15
3.2 Current housing costs ........................................................................................ 18
3.3 Homeownership simulation scenarios .............................................................. 20
3.4 Summary ............................................................................................................ 31
CHAPTER 4 INCOME ADEQUACY IN RETIREMENT ............................................................................ 33
4.1 Introduction ....................................................................................................... 33
4.2 Data and methodology ...................................................................................... 33
4.3 Results and empirical findings ........................................................................... 35
4.4 Summary ............................................................................................................ 40
CHAPTER 5 CONCLUSIONS ................................................................................................................ 43
5.1 Summary of main findings ................................................................................. 43
5.2 Policy implications ............................................................................................. 45
REFERENCES ........................................................................................................................................ 49
APPENDIX I SUPPLEMENTARY RESEARCH FOR CHAPTER 3.................................................................
53
APPENDIX II SUPPLEMENTARY RESEARCH FOR CHAPTER 4 ............................................................... 55
vi | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
LIST OF TABLES
Table 3.1 What % of non-transitioners are constrained by different factors? ................................ 24
Table 3.2 Homeownership rate simulations by age cohort (%) additional scenarios ................... 26
Table 3.3 Homeownership rate simulations for 25-34 cohort (%) .................................................. 28
Table 4.1 Poverty line (AROP) measures of income adequacy ........................................................ 36
Table 4.2 Poverty gap for various measures of income adequacy .................................................. 38
Table 4.3 Logistic regression of the factors associated with AROP status, baseline simulations,
broader income measure ................................................................................................. 40
Table A.1 Evidence of likelihood of receiving gift / amount by recipient characteristics ................ 53
Table A.2 25th percentile house price by NUTS 3 region 2019 ..................................................... 53
Table A.3 Logistic regression of the factors associated with AROP, baseline simulations, narrow
income measure ............................................................................................................... 55
LIST OF FIGURES
Figure 1.1 Homeownership rates by decade of birth cohort .............................................................. 2
Figure 2.1 Trends in housing costs (year-on-year change, %) ........................................................... 12
Figure 2.2 Tenure shares Ireland ....................................................................................................... 13
Figure 2.3 Housing supply changes ESB connections overall and per 1,000 persons
aged 20-50 ........................................................................................................................ 14
Figure 3.1 % Homeowners by age cohort 1987-2015 ....................................................................... 16
Figure 3.2 % Households in housing tenures by age cohort 2018-2019 ........................................... 17
Figure 3.3 Mean housing cost-to-income ratio (HCTI) % by tenure and age cohort ........................ 18
Figure 3.4 % Households with high housing costs (HCTI>30%) by age cohort .................................. 19
Figure 3.5 Overview of static tenure assignment method ................................................................ 21
Figure 3.6 % Homeowners after static tenure transition, by age cohort .......................................... 23
Figure 3.7 % Homeowners 25-34 cohort different house price and income growth scenarios .... 29
Figure A.1 Distribution of after housing costs income, by scenario (broad definition) .................... 56
Figure A.2 Distribution of after housing costs income, by scenario (narrow definition) .................. 56
Abbreviations | vii
ABBREVIATIONS
AHC After housing cost
AROP At risk of poverty
AT-HOME Affordability and Tenure Housing Microsimulation Engine
BHC Before housing cost
CSO Central Statistics Office
HAP Housing Assistance Payment
PRSI Pay Related Social Insurance
RAS Rental Assistance Scheme
RS Rent Supplement
SILC Survey on Income and Living Conditions
SPA State Pension Age
TILDA The Irish Longitudinal Study on Ageing
TRIAM TILDA Retirement Income Adequacy Model
Executive summary | ix
EXECUTIVE SUMMARY
CONTEXT AND RESEARCH RATIONALE
In recent years, Ireland has experienced a notable decline in homeownership and
a rise in the proportion of households in private rental accommodation.
Concurrently, the cost of both rents and house prices have risen markedly and
affordability challenges in terms of meeting housing costs have been well
documented. While these challenges are immediate in terms of the housing costs
burden, a longer-term issue arises as to how renting households will manage the
financial adjustment to retirement with ongoing rent payments. This transition
historically in Ireland has been smoothed by high homeownership rates and
mortgage amortisation which lowered the cost of housing payments and increased
financial assets. Indeed, existing international evidence suggests that being a
homeowner can provide a double dividend of lowering housing costs and
increasing assets in retirement. This can help manage changes to income in
retirement and allow households to maintain their standard of living.
The continued requirement to cover housing costs for renters in retirement can be
seen as an additional vulnerability in terms of retirement income adequacy in
Ireland, over and above the general concern of sufficient pension income. While
considerable research to date has documented this well-known challenge of
providing a sufficient standard of living in retirement for many households in
Ireland, the drop in the homeownership rate layers an additional complication in
terms of the policy challenge.
To address these related issues, this report explores indicative future paths for
homeownership rates in Ireland and explores the impact in terms of income
poverty in retirement. Using data from the Survey on Income and Living Conditions
(SILC) and the Irish Longitudinal Study on Ageing (TILDA), we consider a number of
scenarios to assess the possibility of renting households becoming homeowners,
and then test the impact on income poverty rates if households were to continue
to have rental costs into retirement.
SUMMARY OF MAIN FINDINGS
A number of key findings emerge from this research:
Findings on homeownership rates
Ireland has experienced a marked drop in homeownership rates in recent
years. This has been particularly acute for younger-aged households, with the
share of 25-34s who owned their own home halving between 2004 and 2015,
falling from 60 per cent to just 30 per cent. This has continued to fall for
x | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
households aged 25-34 and 35-44 since 2015. For these age groups, the
predominant tenure for non-homeowners is private rental with no policy
support (such as HAP, RAS etc).
At present the share of households with high housing costs
1
clearly falls with
age. Over 1-in-5 households aged 25-34 face high housing costs, compared to
around 1-in-17 aged 55-64 and only 1-in-100 of those currently aged 65+. For
all age cohorts the incidence of high housing costs is notably higher for non-
homeowners.
We undertake a range of simulations that vary income, credit, savings and
house prices to explore the possible transition of current renters to
homeownership. The results indicate a likely, and considerable, drop in the
achievable rate of homeownership relative to previous generations (and
current retirees) across all age groups;
o Homeownership rates are around 10 percentage points lower
(approximately 80 per cent) for those currently aged 55-64 and 45-54
compared with current retirees (approximately 90 per cent); this
differential is unlikely to close substantially for these groups given their
position in the lifecycle;
o The homeownership rate for those aged 35-44 is currently 58 per cent.
Our scenarios indicate that this age cohort could, at a maximum, reach
a homeownership rate of 71 per cent through home purchases in the
open market;
o There is likely greater uncertainty over the 25-34 age group given their
age and lifecycle earnings prospects. However, while alternative
scenarios (e.g. down-payment supports) would boost this cohorts’
homeownership rates, they remain significantly below those of
previous cohorts, and this is unlikely to change considerably unless their
income growth outpaces house price growth for a sustained period;
o As a result, the simulated rate of homeownership is lower again for the
youngest aged group, 25-34, with approximately one-in-two
households becoming homeowners in the majority of scenarios
explored.
Multiple factors are likely causing the drop in homeownership rates including
labour market dynamics, the relative growth of house prices and incomes,
supply bottlenecks and credit availability. Using a static model, we do not
formally test for the drivers of homeownership in this report, nor do we take
1
High housing costs is defined as a housing cost-to-income ratio greater than 30 per cent.
Executive summary | xi
account of possible demographic changes (e.g. migration) that would change
the demand for housing.
Findings on income adequacy of future cohorts
We explore the likely impact of lower rates of homeownership on measures
of income poverty for Irish individuals approaching retirement. Using data on
the group who are due to retire over the next five years (92 per cent of whom
own their home), we estimate that income poverty
2
in retirement rises from
9 per cent on a before housing costs basis to 14 per cent on an after housing
costs basis.
Lower rates of homeownership are likely to lead to substantially higher after
housing costs income poverty rates. To demonstrate the impact of changes in
homeownership on income adequacy, and linking to our research above on
lower homeownership for younger households, we simulate income poverty
rates for those approaching retirement would reach 31 per cent under a low
homeownership scenario of 63 per cent, 28 per cent under a medium
homeownership scenario of 70 per cent, and 21 per cent under a high
homeownership scenario of 78 per cent, compared to 14 per cent under the
baseline homeownership rate of 92 per cent.
Our analysis suggests that women, those with lower levels of education and
those living alone during working life are particularly vulnerable to income
poverty in retirement after housing costs are taken into account.
POLICY CONSIDERATIONS
A number of considerations for policy arise from our research:
Irelands pension system (both public and private) has to date leveraged the
double dividendassociated with homeownership lower housing costs and
higher assets in retirement. It is unlikely that homeownership rates will be as
high in future and therefore consideration will have to be given to the most
appropriate policy response. This could include policies aimed at addressing
the housing costs element, the income adequacy element, or both.
Policies could be targeted to improve incomes of older households or to
incentivise renting households to build up more resources earlier in their
lifecycle while in employment.
Income-based support for older households could come in the form of
targeted supports to those groups of households most at risk of income
poverty. This would be more efficient in deadweight terms than blanket
measures to raise state pension rates which would also be fiscally expensive.
2
This is based on the official at risk of poverty threshold and a broaddefinition of income. The broaddefinition of
income includes income from state and supplementary pensions, as well as the annuitised value of net financial assets
(i.e. savings, stocks/shares, investment property, etc., minus any outstanding non-mortgage debt).
xii | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
Indeed, the latter approach may not be fiscally sustainable in the context of
the broader demographic pressures.
The second area of intervention that shifts the housing costs risk in retirement
is to directly intervene for households with housing costs challenges. The
availability of a targeted instrument such as an income supplement or rent
subsidy to directly cover housing costs for those households who are proven
to be in housing costs distress could feature as part of the future policy
architecture.
However, the availability of, and even the signalling of, such instruments could
alter the incentives for households to sufficiently accumulate resources earlier
in their working lives. Furthermore, such extensive subsidy supports for those
living in private sector accommodation risks adding to rental inflation and the
costs are likely to be prohibitively expensive for the State given the scale of
the projected fall in homeownership for future retirement cohorts.
More generally in terms of broader housing policy, interventions at earlier
stages of the lifecycle are critical to help lower the housing costs future
cohorts will face in retirement. Instruments targeting increased supply which
impact the share of homeowners, increased direct provision of social housing
or which develop alternative, non-market renting cohorts such as cost rental
and expanded social housing can all help to lower the cost of housing at
retirement.
It is however worth noting that while the scenarios in this report attempt to
provide an indicative range for future homeownership rates and the impact
on households income adequacy, any assessment that extrapolates across
such a long horizon is subject to considerable uncertainty. In particular, the
current 25-34 age cohort may be expected to experience further career
progression and income growth, which leads to considerable uncertainty in
projecting their likely homeownership rates in retirement.
In addition, there is also uncertainty about the extent to which current (and
future) housing policy initiatives may increase the share of future
homeowners and/or ensure lower and more stable housing costs for future
cohorts of retirees. Therefore, there is certainly time for policies to influence
the outcomes of this research from both a housing tenure and income support
perspective.
However, given future demographic projections and associated sustainability
challenges, it is unlikely the State will also be able to fully carry the cost burden
for the challenge of higher housing costs in retirement. Therefore, developing
a policy strategy which mixes lifetime incentives to accumulate retirement
assets during employment with an adequate safety net is most likely to be
required.
Introduction | 1
CHAPTER 1
Introduction
1.1 CONTEXT
A key area of policy concern is the extent to which those who are retired will have
adequate resources to fund their consumption in retirement (European
Commission, 2021; Government of Ireland, 2018; Mulligan et al., 2019). Assessing
the adequacy of incomes in retirement is not a straightforward task, particularly
for those who have not yet retired. A number of assumptions are required to
simulate the level of retirement income, while there are multiple definitions of
what one may want to consider as retirement income. In this report, we consider
adequacy with reference to some fixed level of income deemed sufficient to buy
essential goods and services: the so-called poverty-lineapproach.
3
Much of the existing work in this area in the Irish context has focused on the extent
to which those who are either already retired or very close to retirement are at risk
of inadequate incomes in retirement (Beirne et al., 2020; Bercholz et al., 2019;
Nivakoski, 2014; Nivakoski and Barrett, 2019). While assessments of retirement
income adequacy are sensitive to the measure of adequacy adopted, and the
definition of retirement income, the most recent Irish estimates suggest that
approximately 9 per cent of those approaching the state pension age (SPA) over
the period 2022-2027 would be at risk of poverty using the 60 per cent of median
household disposable income poverty threshold, based on a definition of
retirement income that includes state and supplementary pension income, as well
as non-primary residence asset income (Beirne et al., 2020).
However, demographic, social and economic changes over recent decades mean
that future cohorts of retirees are likely to look very different to the current cohort
of retirees. One of the most important of these dimensions is housing tenure and
costs. According to the 2016 Census of Population, over 85 per cent of those aged
65+ owned their own home, the vast majority outright (Central Statistics Office,
2017). In addition, most of those aged 65+ renting do so from a local authority or
voluntary body, and thus may expect to have low and relatively stable housing
costs in retirement (Doolan et al., 2022). However, the age at which two-thirds of
the cohort own their own home (with or without a mortgage) has been increasing
steadily over time, from 28 years of age in 1991 to 41 in 2016 (Central Statistics
Office, 2017). This implies substantial differences in the projected tenure and
housing costs of younger cohorts.
3
See (Beirne et al., 2020) and (Crawford and O’Dea, 2012) for more detailed discussions of the conceptual and
measurement issues involved in assessing retirement income adequacy.
2 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
These cohort-level changes in housing tenure can be illustrated in greater detail in
Figure 1.1. While more than 60 per cent of those born in the 1960s lived in a home
they or their partner owned by age 30, this proportion had fallen to 39 per cent for
those born in the 1970s and 32 per cent for those born in the early 1980s. While
there may be some catch-up at later ages (in part due to changing patterns of
family formation), the figure shows that rates of homeownership for previous
cohorts tend to level off after age 45 (Roantree et al., 2021).
FIGURE 1.1 HOMEOWNERSHIP RATES BY DECADE OF BIRTH COHORT
Source: Reproduced from Roantree et al. (2021) using the Survey of Income Distribution, Poverty and Usage of State Services; the Living
in Ireland survey; and the Survey on Income and Living Conditions.
Notes: Homeownership defined as being the head or the partner of the head of a household that lives in an owner-occupied dwelling
(i.e. adult children of owner-occupiers not counted as owning their own home).
The drop in homeownership documented above is likely caused by a range of
factors. As discussed in McQuinn et al. (2021), the tightening of credit access rules
following the onset of the financial crisis, coupled with historically low housing
supply and rising demographic demand, have led to rapidly rising house prices and
rents in Ireland. These factors have led to an increasingly evident housing
affordability challenge, in particular for young, urban renting households who have
faced rapidly increasing rental prices (Corrigan et al., 2019). While these problems
are currently acute, the longer-term implications for these households of how to
cover housing costs in retirement (in lower expected homeownership contexts) has
received less attention in the policy or research literature.
0%
20%
40%
60%
80%
100%
20 25 30 35 40 45 50 55
% who own their own home
Age
1940s 1950s 1960s 1970s 1980s 1990s
Introduction | 3
1.2 EXISTING EVIDENCE
1.2.1 Retirement income adequacy
Most assessments of retirement income adequacy in an Irish context have tended
to focus on those already retired, or close to retirement. For example, using data
from the Irish Longitudinal Study on Ageing (TILDA), Nivakoski (2014) and Nivakoski
and Barrett (2019) found that income replacement rates
4
were highest for women
and those at the bottom of the earnings distribution, more reflecting the lower
earnings of these groups immediately prior to retirement than high levels of
resources available in retirement. As replacement rates are sensitive to how
income (both pre- and post-retirement) is defined, and generally do not take into
account the wider resources of the household (e.g. from other family members
and/or from assets), or future risks to longevity, investments and healthcare needs
(Knoff et al., 2016), alternative benchmarks are required. An alternative approach
assesses the adequacy of retirement income by determining whether it is sufficient
to meet basic needs (i.e. having enough income to be able to purchase necessities
such as housing, food and clothing). This is assessed in terms of whether retirement
resources are below some benchmark of income poverty, typically the at-risk-of-
poverty threshold.
In this context, a recent study attempted to move beyond a single replacement
rate to consider multiple indicators of retirement income adequacy, varying not
only the definition of income, but also the benchmarks used to assess adequacy.
Beirne et al. (2020) used data from TILDA on the cohort of people born between
1955 and 1960 (and therefore expected to reach the state pension age over the
period 2022-2027) to assess the adequacy of their projected income in retirement,
using a variety of different benchmarks and definitions of retirement income.
5
The
analysis found that assessments of income adequacy in retirement were very
sensitive to the benchmark used. Even small changes in the benchmark resulted in
large changes in the proportion assessed as having inadequate resources in
retirement. For example, moving from a poverty-line benchmark of 60 per cent of
median household disposable income (the current at-risk-of-poverty threshold) to
a 50 per cent of median household disposable income benchmark (the OECD at-
risk-of-poverty threshold) resulted in a sharp fall in those with inadequate levels of
income in retirement (from 9.2 per cent to 3.0 per cent using a broad definition of
income that includes non-primary residence asset income in addition to state and
4
The retirement income replacement rate is defined as the ratio of post-retirement income (from pensions, annuitised
wealth holdings, etc.) to pre-retirement income. The current Pensions Roadmap 2018-2023 aims to ensure that the
state pension, in combination with supplementary pensions, replaces a sufficient proportion (between 50 and 60 per
cent) of an individuals pre-retirement earnings so as to enable them to maintain a reasonable standard of living after
retirement (Government of Ireland, 2018).
5
In this report, we use this model, the TILDA Retirement Income Adequacy Model (TRIAM) developed in Beirne et al.
(2020), to assess the retirement income adequacy of current and future cohorts of retirees on an after housing costs
basis.
4 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
supplementary pension income). In addition, across all benchmarks, broadening
the definition of income in retirement to include financial assets, and further still
to include half the value of owner-occupied housing wealth, substantially reduced
the proportions of those who were considered at risk of having inadequate
resources in retirement. While the issue of whether individuals should draw on
wealth in the form of primary residences to support living standards in retirement
is contentious, less so is that individuals should draw on other forms of wealth.
These results suggested that private non-pension, non-primary residence assets
play an important role in individualspreparedness for retirement.
1.2.2 Housing costs and retirement income adequacy
While the general literature on retirement income adequacy is considerable, few
assessments of retirement income adequacy consider explicitly the role of housing.
Housing can refer to a service (the accommodation that housing provides) and a
capital asset (the dwelling that produces the service) (Fahey and Norris, 2010). One
strand of the literature considers housing from the latter perspective, i.e. as an
asset that can be considered as a source of income in retirement. Fahey (2003)
notes that housing is a valuable asset in retirement which, in principle at least, can
be drawn upon to provide cash income later in life should the need arise (e.g. by
downsizing, equity release, or through family arrangements whereby younger
family members provide support to older family members in return for an explicit
or implicit promise of an eventual bequest). Banks et al. (2005), Crawford and
O’Dea (2012) and Beirne et al. (2020) all considered the role of owner-occupied
housing wealth in their assessments of retirement income adequacy in England
and Ireland, by examining the extent to which these assessments were affected by
the inclusion of half the annuitised value of owner-occupied housing wealth in the
definition of retirement income.
Dewilde and Raeymaeckers (2008) used data from the 2001 European Community
Household Panel (ECHP) to test the idea that housing policies can reduce poverty
in later life by promoting outright ownership, which in turn provides a hidden
source of income (also addressed using earlier data by Fahey et al., 2004a). Across
the ten Member States included in the ECHP (including Ireland), they found that
neither generous pensions nor high ownership rates had the strongest poverty-
reducing potential; lower poverty rates in older age were most strongly associated
with the provision of social housing for older people. Furthermore, they identified
a group of older people who were faced with a double disadvantage, in the sense
that in high homeownership countries, those who did not possess their own homes
also tended to receive low pension benefits.
In a comparative analysis of a selection of countries with differing housing and
pension systems in the early 2000s, Delfani et al. (2014) found little support for the
hypothesis that housing and pensions in older age were to some extent
Introduction | 5
interchangeable; the exception was in countries such as Ireland with high rates of
homeownership, and no mandatory earnings-related pension scheme. A detailed
analysis of the homeownership-pension trade-off in four European countries
(Belgium, Germany, Ireland and the Netherlands) using Survey on Income and
Living Condition (SILC) data for 2009 showed that outright homeownership among
the income-poor older population played a significant role in reducing poverty
(both income poverty and deprivation)
6
in old age (Delfani et al., 2015). In Ireland,
outright homeownership had a particularly strong effect on reducing deprivation
in older age.
Focusing on housing costs, a recent paper used data from the German Socio-
Economic Panel (GSOEP) to examine how rising housing costs over the period
1996-2017 have affected income poverty among the older population (aged 65+)
(Lozano Alcántara and Vogel, 2021). The German case is of particular interest as it
has one of the highest percentages of tenants (48.9 per cent in 2019) in Europe.
They found that the share of tenants aged 65+ at income poverty risk after housing
costs rose from 23.9 per cent in 1996 to 33.9 per cent in 2017, while for
homeowners the share remained broadly stable (and much lower) throughout the
period (at approximately 6-8 per cent). A Blinder-Oaxaca decomposition showed
that changes in housing costs between 1996 and 2017 explained most of the
increase in the old-age income poverty rate over the period.
Using data from Australia for 2017-2018, Bradbury and Saunders (2021) compared
before and after housing costs poverty rates across different population groups.
They hypothesised that the before housing costs measure would over-estimate
poverty among older people who often have low (mainly pension) incomes but also
face low housing costs because many of them own their homes outright. In
contrast, they found that the after housing costs poverty rate for single older
people was substantially higher than the before housing costs rate (23.4 per cent
vs. 15.9 per cent), and largely the same on a before and after housing costs basis
for older couples (at approximately 9 per cent). Examining trends over time since
2007, they found that the sharp increase in house prices that has left many
Australians with unpaid mortgages when they reach pension age, and the growing
number of both young and old Australians who are unable to gain access to
homeownership and forced to rely on the private rental market, explained these
patterns.
In the Irish context, Fahey (2003) calculated before and after housing costs at risk
of poverty rates by age cohort using data from 1998. He found that while the after
housing costs poverty rate among older households was 10 percentage points
6
I.e. inability to afford social activities, healthy food, clothing etc.
6 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
lower than the before housing costs poverty rate, it was still high in absolute terms
(at 30 per cent) and was the highest of any age group. This reflected the relatively
low mortgage costs across the age cohorts observed at this time. Updating the
analysis using data for 2000, Fahey et al. (2004b) found that the contrast between
before and after housing costs income poverty measures was largest for those
aged over 65: the percentage of persons aged 65+ below the before housing costs
income poverty threshold was 43 per cent, in comparison to 34 per cent when
using the after housing costs measure. These figures have to be interpreted in the
light of the patterns of income poverty across age cohorts at that time; in contrast
to now, older adults (aged 65+) were at the highest risk of (before housing cost)
poverty in the early 2000s, with 43.3 per cent in income poverty in 2000, compared
with 16.9 per cent of the population aged 18-64, and 24.9 per cent of children aged
under 18 (Fahey et al., 2004b).
7
To our knowledge, there has been no research of
after housing costs income poverty in Ireland since the early 2000s, though the CSO
has recently begun to publish such estimates as a supplement to the official
estimates of poverty and deprivation (Central Statistics Office, 2021b).
8
A particularly important aspect in the homeownership debate, and one which has
focused research where younger adults are considered, is the extent to which
saving for homeownership and/or rental payments affects how younger adults
save for retirement. For example, Crawford and Simpson (2020) found that higher
house prices reduced the probability that young adults (aged 21-35) in England,
particularly those working in the public sector and in the middle of the earnings
distribution, enrolled in a private pension, although the magnitude of the effect
was small. Yates and Bradbury (2010) examined the potential for asset-based
welfare
9
to protect households from poverty after retirement by focusing on the
role of homeownership in preventing poverty among older Australians and on
likely future trends in asset accumulation. They found that although asset-based
welfare has the potential to ease the fiscal constraints faced by the state, it may
well lead to poorer social insurance outcomes for households with limited saving
capacity over their lifetime. Using data for Australia (which has high rates of
homeownership), they showed that older households who missed out on
homeownership were multiply disadvantaged: they had lower non-housing
wealth, lower disposable incomes and higher housing costs in retirement than
homeowners and they had significantly higher after housing poverty rates.
7
In 2020, children (aged 0-17) had the highest income poverty rate (16.4 per cent) across the age groups, while those
aged 65+ had the lowest (9.8 per cent) (CSO, 2021b).
8
The indicator of after housing costs income is calculated based on an alternative measure of equivalised income,
excluding the total rent paid and mortgage interest. The total rent paid includes housing supports such as the Housing
Assistance Payment (HAP), Rent Supplement, Rental Assistance Scheme (RAS) which were included in the household
income. Any person with an equivalised income after rent and mortgage interest of less than 60 per cent of the median
before rent and mortgage interest is considered at risk of poverty after rent and mortgage interest (i.e. the same
threshold is used for calculating the rate before and after rent and mortgage interest is deducted) (CSO, 2021b).
9
Asset-based welfare refers to the use of policies to incentivise accumulation of asset wealth (including homeownership)
in working life, in order to fund consumption in retirement.
Introduction | 7
Projections suggested that this group will grow in size in the coming decades (see
also Yates et al., 2008).
1.3 CONTRIBUTION AND REPORT STRUCTURE
Given the existing literature, both internationally and for Ireland, there is a clear
gap in terms of research covering the intersection of the changing nature of
housing costs and tenure and the adequacy of income in retirement. The purpose
of this report is to address this gap and to explore the following research questions:
What is the expected proportion of homeowners and renters in Ireland going
forward?
What is the typical housing costs burden for these households?
What implications do projected tenure patterns have for the adequacy of
retirement income, in particular for renters?
More specifically, our contribution is as follows. We build on an existing model of
retirement income adequacy developed at the ESRI to assess the impact of housing
costs on retirement income adequacy. This model, TRIAM, uses data from the Irish
Longitudinal Study on Ageing (TILDA) to simulate the incomes in retirement of a
cohort of individuals born between 1955 and 1960 (who can expect to reach the
state pension age (SPA) of 67 between 2022 and 2027) (Beirne et al., 2020).
10
The
model uses similar data and methods to those used in the UK to assess retirement
income adequacy (Banks et al., 2005; Crawford and O’Dea, 2012). In this model,
the adequacy of retirement income is assessed against a number of poverty line
benchmarks of adequacy. Different definitions of income (i.e. state and
supplementary pension income, adding financial assets, etc.) are also examined.
Cohort-level scenarios of tenure and housing costs are developed using the ESRIs
micro-simulation tool for assessing housing affordability and tenure (AT-HOME).
This tool considers tenure transitions by households and provides a number of
different scenarios for savings, house prices and incomes to provide housing
tenure proportions. This provides an age-cohort based projection of the share of
renters and homeowners as well as an exploration of the factors that act as the
major barrier to homeownership (for example insufficient savings or income).
These tenure-share projections are incorporated into the TRIAM, coupled with
housing costs estimates for future renters, in a number of stages. In the first stage,
the sensitivity of estimates of retirement income adequacy for the 1955-1960
cohort to the inclusion of housing costs is assessed (i.e. before and after housing
10
When the model was developed (2019), the SPA was expected to increase to 67 from 2021.
8 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
costs measures of poverty are calculated). In the second stage, we assess the
broader implications of projected cohort-level differences in housing tenure and
costs (based on simulations from the AT-HOME model) for before and after
housing costs estimates of poverty. Three estimates of projected homeownership
rates (high, medium and low based on the AT-HOME modelling results) are used
to illustrate the impact on retirement income adequacy estimates.
The report is structured as follows. Chapter 2 provides a brief overview of the
institutional background and policy context, summarising the current system of
pension payments in Ireland, as well as the key features of the Irish housing
market. Chapter 3 outlines the results of the modelling to derive cohort-specific
tenure and housing costs (from the AT-HOME model), while Chapter 4 presents the
results incorporating these projections into assessments of retirement income
adequacy using TRIAM. The final chapter, Chapter 5, of the report discusses the
findings, drawing out implications for policy.
Policy context | 9
CHAPTER 2
Policy context
2.1 THE IRISH PENSION SYSTEM
In common with many other OECD countries, the Irish pension system comprises
three main pillars: state, occupational and private pensions (Government of
Ireland, 2018; OECD, 2014; 2021). Data from the 2015 and 2016 Survey on Income
and Living Conditions (SILC) show that nearly 75 per cent of the gross income of
those aged 66+ comes from these sources (Nolan et al., 2019). The latest official
figures show that just under two-thirds of those aged 20 to 69 in employment in
2020 were covered by an occupational or private pension (Central Statistics Office,
2021a).
The first pillar comprises the state (contributory or non-contributory) pension,
which is a largely flat-rate payment (i.e. not earnings-related), payable from age
66. Entitlement to the state pension (contributory) is based on a complex set of
rules, and depends on when the individual first entered employment, the number
of pay-related social insurance (PRSI) contributions, and the average number of
contributions per year.
11
To qualify for the non-contributory state welfare pension,
a person must pass a means test based on both income and wealth, and must be
habitually resident in Ireland (Nivakoski and Barrett, 2019).
12
The State Pension Age (SPA) in Ireland is currently 66, with no provision to defer
any entitlement or to claim it earlier. Prior to 2014, the state pension (transition)
in Ireland was payable at age 65 to individuals who retired from insurable
employment and satisfied certain social insurance contribution conditions. The
state pension (transition) was abolished in 2014. In February 2021, a benefit
payment for those aged 65 who have ceased regular employment or self-
employment and who have the required PRSI contributions was introduced.
The benefit is paid at the same rate as the standard rate of Jobseekers Benefit
(€208 per week) and stops once the person reaches the SPA of 66.
13
11
It is proposed to move to a new total contributions approach(TCA) for determining the level of contributory pension
received by an individual. Under this system, the amount of pensions will be directly proportionate to the number of
social insurance contributions made by a person over his or her working life, rather than the average (Government of
Ireland, 2018). While this was initially intended to be fully rolled out for those retiring in 2020 onwards, those reaching
the SPA are currently being assessed under the existing and TCA systems and given an entitlement corresponding to
the higher of the two.
12
The maximum contributory state pension payable is currently €253.30 per week. The non-contributory state pension
is means-tested and is payable at a maximum rate of €242 for those aged less than 80, and €252 for those aged 80+.
See https://www.citizensinformation.ie/en/social_welfare/social_welfare_payments/older_and_retired_people/ for
further details.
13
See
https://www.citizensinformation.ie/en/social_welfare/social_welfare_payments/older_and_retired_people/paymen
t_for_people_retired_at_65.html for further details.
10 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
For both the contributory and non-contributory state pensions, it was announced
in 2010 that the SPA would further increase to 67 in 2021 and to 68 in 2028
(Government of Ireland, 2010; 2018). However, the planned increase to 67 was
suspended in 2020. The Government established a Commission on Pensions to
examine various issues around the sustainability of the state pension, including the
SPA. The report of the Commission, published in October 2021, recommended that
the SPA increase by three months per year starting from 2028 to reach 67 years in
2031, and at a slower pace (by three months every two years from 2033) to reach
68 in 2039 (Government of Ireland, 2021).
The second pillar comprises occupational pensions, which cover a broad section of
the population.
14
Tax relief at the marginal rate is available for contributions to
approved occupational pension schemes. It is generally not possible to contribute
to an occupational pension scheme after the normal age of retirement. There is no
legal obligation for employers to provide occupational pension schemes, but those
who do not must provide access to at least one Personal Retirement Savings
Account (PRSA). However, public service occupational pension schemes are in
place for staff across the civil service, local authorities, Garda Síochána (Irish
police), the Defence Forces, the health and education sectors and non-commercial
state bodies. In order to increase supplementary pension coverage, particularly in
the private sector, in 2019 the Government announced its intention to introduce a
system of automatic enrolment (OECD, 2021). The details of this Automatic
Enrolment Retirement Savings System were announced in March 2022. From
January 2024, all employees not already in an occupational pension scheme, aged
between 23 and 60 and earning over €20,000 across all of their employments, will
be automatically enrolled. Employer and employee contributions will initially be
1.5 per cent of gross income each (with an additional 0.5 per cent provided by the
State), increasing every three years by 1.5 per cent until they eventually reach 6 per
cent for both employee and employer (and 2 per cent by the State) in year ten
(2034) (Department of Social Protection, 2022).
Finally, the third pillar is a voluntary savings pillar, typically comprised of long-term
personal savings and financial investments used to fund retirement over and above
first and second-pillar arrangements. Private pension schemes are voluntary and
include Retirement Annuity Contracts (RACs), commonly used by the self-
employed, and PRSAs, which were introduced in 2002 as an attempt to increase
the pension coverage among low-coverage employee groups (Nolan et al., 2019).
14
In 2020, two-thirds of workers had an occupational and/or private pension. Of those workers who had an occupational
and/or private pension in 2020, 69.7 per cent had occupational pension cover only (from current or previous
employment), 12.3 per cent had personal pension coverage only and 18 per cent had both (Central Statistics Office,
2021a).
Policy context | 11
The Pensions Roadmap 2018-2023 sets out Government policy in relation to six key
strands of pensions policy, including state pension reform and automatic
enrolment (Government of Ireland, 2018). It recognises that while the state
pension provides basic protection against income poverty in old age, it is not
designed to ensure a high level of retirement income adequacy. Therefore, the
state pension should, in most cases, be combined with supplementary pension
arrangements in the form of occupational and personal pension products. While
international assessments of Irelands pension system highlight future
sustainability challenges, particularly if increases to the SPA are deferred
(European Commission, 2021; OECD, 2021), there has been little or no discussion
of the potential impact of cohort-specific changes in housing costs on the
retirement income adequacy of future cohorts.
15
However, in recognition of the
growing importance of housing costs in household budgets, the CSO started to
publish both before and after housing costs measures of income poverty in 2020
(Central Statistics Office, 2021b).
2.2 THE IRISH HOUSING MARKET
Affordability of, and access to, housing has become one of the critical policy issues
in Ireland in the past number of years. This is due to the culmination of worsening
affordability in both rental and house purchase markets as chronic supply
shortages and rising prices have persisted.
Figure 2.1 documents the trend in housing and rental price changes for the period
2006 to 2022. In the immediate aftermath of the financial crisis, both house prices
and rents dropped considerably reflecting the general economic turmoil of the
period. As the economy began to rebound in 2013/2014, the inflation rate for
housing and rental prices began to recover. In the home purchase market, prices
began to rapidly increase but cooled somewhat in 2015 as the Central Bank of
Ireland introduced a suite of macroprudential mortgage measures which capped
the loan-to-income and loan-to-value ratios for borrowers. The aim of these
measures was to build bank and borrower resilience as well as break the
procyclicality in credit cycles between housing and credit markets (Grace et al.,
2015). House prices began to increase in 2016 and 2017 but tapered off before the
COVID-19 pandemic. Inflationary pressures rebounded in 2021.
15
The European Commission notes that the housing costs overburden rate (1.5 per cent) for the current cohort of over
65s in Ireland is considerably below the EU average (9.8 per cent). The housing costs overburden rate is the share of
older people living in households where the total housing costs represent more than 40 per cent of the total disposable
household income (European Commission, 2021).
12 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
FIGURE 2.1 TRENDS IN HOUSING COSTS (YEAR-ON-YEAR CHANGE, %)
Source: CSO House Price Index and CPI data (rental indicators).
Notes: Percentage change in index over 12 months reported.
While the macroprudential mortgage measures act to limit feedback loops
between credit and house prices,
16
these policies can lead to other externalities
such as tighter access to credit for first time homebuyers. Recent research suggests
that Irish households do face credit access constraints from a lack of sufficient
equity accumulation as well as tight income leverage limits (McQuinn et al., 2021;
Kelly and Mazza, 2019). To attempt to deal with these externalities, a number of
policy supports were introduced into the market such as the Help-to-Buy scheme
which provides for a tax rebate towards house purchase of new homes by first time
buyers and the Rebuilding Ireland Home Loan, a direct local authority loan product
(O’Toole and Slaymaker, 2020). Further measures to deal with credit and leverage
access (in the form of general and local authority specific shared-equity schemes)
are forthcoming as part of the Housing for All’ plan announced in 2021.
17
In the rental sector, prices have also risen rapidly in recent years. The sector has
been accommodating a larger and larger share of the population relative to
historical norms (see Figure 2.2) and this has led to considerable rises in the
average level of rents in the period since 2014. To counteract the rapid inflationary
impulses, rent control policies have been introduced to put a cap on inflation.
These Rent Pressure Zones placed limits on the allowable inflation rates per
property for rental tenancies in specific geographic zones (see Coffey et al., 2022).
16
Research has shown that the macroprudential rules have limited house price inflation in Ireland (McQuinn, 2021).
17
See De Burca et al. (2021) for a review of the First Home shared equity scheme.
-25
-20
-15
-10
-5
0
5
10
15
20
25
2006M01
2006M08
2007M03
2007M10
2008M05
2008M12
2009M07
2010M02
2010M09
2011M04
2011M11
2012M06
2013M01
2013M08
2014M03
2014M10
2015M05
2015M12
2016M07
2017M02
2017M09
2018M04
2018M11
2019M06
2020M01
2020M08
2021M03
2021M10
%
House Prices Private Rents Local Authority Rents
Policy context | 13
FIGURE 2.2 TENURE SHARES IRELAND
Source: CSO Census of Population, various years.
The inflationary conditions in both the house purchase and rental sectors have
given rise to serious concerns about housing affordability, with a number of
research studies pointing to affordability challenges for subgroups of the
population (low income, urban, private renters) (Corrigan et al., 2019; O’Toole et
al., 2020).
One of the oft-cited reasons behind the rapid price escalation is chronic shortage
of available properties and that new housing completions are well below estimates
of demographic demand (Bergin and Garcia-Rodriguez, 2020). Following the
financial crisis, new housing production in Ireland fell dramatically and has been
slow to recover as the economy has rebounded. Figure 2.3 displays the total
number of electricity connections in Ireland per year, a proxy for the number of
new housing units (left hand bar). The figure also displays (in red) the number of
completions per 1,000 persons aged 20-50 in the population. Given that this age
bracket is the most likely to provide new forming households, it is a useful proxy
for the demographic pressures coming from this group. Current new supply is well
below the historical levels shown in the data.
A range of policy supports have been introduced in recent years to attempt to
alleviate supply bottlenecks. These policies typically fall into three broad policy
groups: a) those that attempt to deal with the cost of construction such as the site
services fund and the local housing infrastructure activation fund (LIHAF);
0%
10%
20%
30%
40%
50%
60%
70%
80%
90%
100%
1991 2002 2006 2011 2016
Own Outright Other Renter Local Authority Renter
14 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
b) policies to provide financing for building projects such as the establishment of
the Land Development Agency (LDA) and Home Building Finance Ireland (HBFI);
and c) policies to lessen time frictions in the planning process. While the number
of housing commencements has recovered in 2021, actual completions continue
to remain below any reasonable estimates of demographic demand.
FIGURE 2.3 HOUSING SUPPLY CHANGES ESB CONNECTIONS OVERALL AND PER 1,000
PERSONS AGED 20-50
Source: CSO NDA04ESB Connections dataset.
Given these housing challenges, there are a number of more recent and long-
standing policies to deal with affordability for lower-income renters outside the
suite of supports that are aimed at the homeownership transition. The bulk of the
policy support is aimed towards those low-income households whose
circumstances are such that they qualify for social housing provision. For this
population cohort a number of supports are available. First, local authorities
provide accommodation directly to social housing tenants who pay an income-
based differential rent. Subsidies are also provided through the Rental
Accommodation Scheme (RAS) and the Housing Assistance Payment (HAP)
whereby the tenant occupies a property in the private rental sector, but the local
authority pays a top-up to the landlord above the differential rent level (paid by
the tenant). Short-term income support is also available for households through
the Rent Supplement (RS) scheme. A more thorough overview of these schemes
and the mechanisms by which they operate can be found in Doolan et al. (2022)
while a documentation of their evolution overtime is contained in Corrigan and
Watson (2019).
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
0
10,000
20,000
30,000
40,000
50,000
60,000
70,000
80,000
90,000
100,000
Connections per 1000 persons Connections
Housing tenure and cost scenarios | 15
CHAPTER 3
Housing tenure and cost scenarios
Given the housing market context, and the observed lowering of the
homeownership rate in Ireland, consideration must be given as how persistent this
pattern may remain and what the likely implications are for income adequacy in
retirement. Within this context, the purpose of this chapter is threefold. First, we
examine current housing tenure patterns for different age cohorts and how these
have changed over time. Second, we analyse how the proportion of income spent
on housing costs varies across tenures and age groups. Third, we use the ESRIs
Affordability and Tenure Housing Microsimulation Engine (AT-HOME) tool to
simulate a series of scenarios for homeownership rates for different age cohorts
based on various assumptions around credit access, house prices, incomes and
rental prices. While homeownership may not be the appropriate tenure for certain
households and high levels of homeownership are not necessarily desirable,
homeownership in retirement provides security in the form of low and stable
housing costs, as well as an asset that can be drawn upon as a potential source of
income (Fahey, 2003; Fahey and Norris, 2010). It must be noted that our
assessment of the rate of homeownership focuses on the ability of households to
become homeowners through house purchase and not channels such as whole (or
part) home inheritance. The findings from this chapter will then be used to
examine how housing costs are likely to impact retirement income adequacy for
different age cohorts in Chapter 4.
3.1 HOUSING TENURE
As noted in Chapter 2, the share of homeowners in Ireland has been declining since
2006. To explore this issue in more detail, using data from the Household Budget
Surveys, Figure 3.1 presents the share of homeowners in different age cohorts and
how this has varied over time. Between 1987 and 2004 ownership rates were fairly
stable across the different age groups; rising slightly over the period for the over
35s but falling around 5 percentage points for 25-34s. However, between 2004 and
2015 there was a notable decline in homeownership across those aged 25-64. The
share of 55-64 year olds owning their own home fell nearly 10 percentage points
over this period, while for those aged 35-44, by 2015 it had fallen to 65 per cent,
having fluctuated between 80-85 per cent between 1987 and 2004. The starkest
decline was for the youngest households in our analysis with the share of 25-34s
who owned their own home halving between 2004 and 2015, falling from 60 per
cent to just 30 per cent.
16 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
FIGURE 3.1 % HOMEOWNERS BY AGE COHORT 1987-2015
Source: Authorscalculations using Household Budget Surveys 1987-2015.
Notes: Homeowners includes both outright owners and owners with a mortgage.
The Household Budget Survey figures presented in Figure 3.1 are only available for
the period up to 2015. The period from 2015 onwards has seen tighter access to
credit with the introduction of macroprudential mortgage regulations, as well as
significant growth in house prices, as shown in Chapter 2. From Figure 3.2, which
uses Survey on Income and Living Conditions (SILC) data for 2018-2019, we see that
the shares of households aged 25-34 and 35-44 who are homeowners have
continued to fall further since 2015, standing at 27 per cent and 58 per cent
respectively for 2018-2019. Ownership rates for those aged 45 and over have
remained similar since 2015.
Regarding the levels of homeownership, Figure 3.2 shows that around 90 per cent
of those in or approaching retirement age (65+) own their own homes. The vast
majority own outright, with fewer than 3 per cent of this age group still making
mortgage payments. Among those who are renting, the majority are in receipt of
some form of housing supports (either living in local authority provided
accommodation or in private sector accommodation with state housing supports).
Fewer than 2 per cent of this cohort live in the private rental sector without
supports. For the subsequent cohort, those currently aged 55-64, the
homeownership rate is around 80 per cent, 10 percentage points lower than the
65+ group. Again, the majority of renters are in receipt of supports, but 5 per cent
of this cohort do live unaided in the private rental sector. The ownership rate for
those aged 45-54 is just under 80 per cent, slightly lower but similar to the 55-64
group. By contrast, far fewer of the subsequent 35-44 cohort are currently
homeowners, with the rate standing at a much lower 58 per cent. For the youngest
cohort (25-34), only 27 per cent currently own their own home, with just over half
of this age group renting unsupported in the private sector.
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
1987 1994 1999 2004 2009 2015
% Homeowners
25-34 35-44 45-54 55-64 65+
Housing tenure and cost scenarios | 17
FIGURE 3.2 % HOUSEHOLDS IN HOUSING TENURES BY AGE COHORT 2018-2019
Source: Authorscalculations from Survey on Income and Living Conditions (SILC) 2018 and 2019.
Notes: The group rental with supports includes households in in the private rental sector who also report paying rent to a local
authority i.e. HAP or Rental Accommodation Scheme recipients, as well as those living in local authority owned properties.
Households who responded that they are living in their property rent free are omitted.
While there may be some degree of homeownership catch-up at later ages,
particularly regarding the youngest age group (in part reflecting increased
education, delayed entry into the workforce and delayed patterns of household
formation), ownership rates for previous birth cohorts have tended to level off by
40-45 (see Figure 1.1). Corlett and Judge (2017) find a similar tapering off of
homeownership rates after 40 in the UK. These findings are consistent with the
fact that banks are typically only willing to offer a mortgage term up to retirement
age and therefore the maximum permissible mortgage term begins to decline after
this point, rendering ownership more challenging.
Corlett and Judge (2017) also find that in the UK both levels and the growth rates
in homeownership between the ages of 30-40 are lower for younger age cohorts.
They conclude the fall in homeownership rates among younger families observed
in the wake of the financial crisis is therefore not likely to fully reverse. Similarly,
Stebbing and Spies-Butcher (2016) find that the rate of catch-up is declining in
Australia and also and conclude that falls in homeownership for younger cohorts
are unlikely to be fully reversed in time. These findings are consistent with Arundel
and Doling (2017) who argue that declines in homeownership are not solely due to
the financial crisis, but that this merely accelerated pre-existing labour market
dynamics such as increased labour market insecurity and are therefore not likely
to be reversed. For Ireland, such a large gap between the ownership rates of the
44-54 and 35-44 groups therefore raises the question of how much this gap is likely
to narrow. We return to this in Section 3.3.1.
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
25-34 35-44 45-54 55-64 65+
%
Rental - Supports
Rental - No Supports
Mortgaged
Own outright
18 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
3.2 CURRENT HOUSING COSTS
A critical issue in the policy considerations around the Irish housing market is the
issue of high housing costs for particular cohorts of the population. Figure 3.3
presents the mean share of net income spent on housing payment costs by tenure
and age cohort. We define housing payment costs as either rental or mortgage
payments. It does not therefore take into account maintenance, insurance and
other costs associated with housing (such as utilities). The high levels of outright
homeownership for those aged 65+, documented above, mean that on average
these homeowners are currently only paying 0.5 per cent of their income on
mortgage costs, as the vast majority have no housing payment costs. The roughly
3 per cent still with a mortgage are paying an average of 22 per cent of net income
on payments, similar to the 21.6 per cent paid by private renters not in receipt of
housing supports. For all other age groups, non-supported private renters are
clearly paying a higher share of income on their housing costs than other tenures.
While mortgaged households typically pay no more than 20-21 per cent on
average, private renters not in receipt of housing supports in the youngest cohort
(25-34), as well as those aged 45-54, are on average paying 27 per cent of their
incomes on rent. In contrast, the housing payment-to-income ratios of local
authority renters are much lower and fairly consistent regardless of age, ranging
from 11-13.5 per cent on average.
FIGURE 3.3 MEAN HOUSING COST-TO-INCOME RATIO (HCTI) % BY TENURE AND AGE COHORT
Source: Authorscalculations from Survey on Income and Living Conditions (SILC) 2018 and 2019.
Notes: Owner (all) includes both those who own outright and those who are mortgaged homeowners. We omit housing cost-to-income
ratios for supported renters living in private rental sector accommodation due to the difficulties associated with capturing the
rents actually paid by these tenants in SILC (see Doolan et al., 2022, for more information).
0
5
10
15
20
25
30
25-34 35-44 45-54 55-64 65+
Owner (all) Mortgaged PR - no supports LA rent
Housing tenure and cost scenarios | 19
Figure 3.4 presents the share of households in each age cohort faced with high
housing costs. We define high housing costs as having a housing cost-to-income
ratio (HCTI) greater than 30 per cent, a commonly used benchmark for high housing
costs (Corrigan et al., 2019). At present the share of households with high housing
costs clearly falls with age. Just over 1-in-5 households aged 25-34 face high
housing costs under this definition, compared to around 1-in-17 aged 55-64 and
only 1-in-100 of those currently aged 65+. For all age cohorts the incidence of high
housing costs is notably higher for non-homeowners.
FIGURE 3.4 % HOUSEHOLDS WITH HIGH HOUSING COSTS (HCTI>30%) BY AGE COHORT
Source: Survey on Income and Living Conditions (SILC) 2018 and 2019.
Notes: Insufficient observations to report share of non-homeowner households aged 65+ with HCTI>30 per cent. Includes all households
with housing payment costs i.e. all but outright owners.
Figures 3.3 and 3.4 highlight the challenges associated with declining
homeownership rates. As noted, while homeownership may not be the
appropriate tenure for certain households and high levels of homeownership are
not necessarily desirable, homeownership in retirement provides security in the
form of low and stable housing costs, as well as an asset that can be drawn upon
as a potential source of income in retirement. Indeed, as highlighted in Section 1.2,
in the literature homeownership and public pensions are often framed as
substitutes in countries with high rates of homeownership (Delfani et al., 2014).
Additionally, Norris (2016) notes how the Irish welfare system has traditionally
focused on property redistribution, with income redistribution and provision of
state services relegated to a secondary objective. As such, high homeownership in
Ireland may have allowed these households to counteract low public or private
income sources in retirement. If the trends of reduced homeownership outlined
above persist into retirement, a substantial portion of future retirement cohorts
will be faced with housing payment costs in their retirement. We now turn to
modelling the likelihood that current renters in different age groups will be able to
transition into homeownership.
0
5
10
15
20
25
25-34 35-44 45-54 55-64 65+
% Households with HCTI>30%
All Non-Homeowners
20 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
3.3 HOMEOWNERSHIP SIMULATION SCENARIOS
3.3.1 Overview: Affordability and Tenure Housing Microsimulation
Engine (AT-HOME)
Having observed the current tenure structure of Irish households, in this section
we use the Affordability and Tenure Housing Microsimulation Engine (AT-HOME)
outlined in McQuinn et al. (2021) to simulate the likelihood of current rental
households in different age cohorts being able to transition to homeownership
under a prudent credit risk assessment policy and current market conditions and
regulations. This assessment has two stages: (i) determining whether a household
is inherently high credit risk and (ii) an assessment of whether a household could
pass the current credit requirements (such as the macroprudential mortgage
regulations) regarding wealth, income and affordability. For this analysis we
combine the 2018 and 2019 waves of the nationally representative Survey on
Income and Living Conditions (SILC). A diagrammatic overview of our AT-HOME
simulation model is presented in Figure 3.5.
Broadly this can be considered a static style modelling approach in that it uses data
on the incomes, employment characteristics, expenditures and housing costs of
existing households and therefore does not focus on household formation or more
dynamic demographic changes (e.g. migration and birth rates) that will
undoubtedly impact the housing market over time. While these aspects are
important, they are not the focus of this work. Our analysis can therefore be
thought of as assessing the proportion of current households in each age cohort
that are: a) currently homeowners and b) likely to be able to become homeowners.
We focus on five age bands: 25-34; 35-44; 45-54; 55-64; and 65+. We only include
cohorts aged 25 and over in our analysis as we do not model the household
formation process specifically. When interpreting our findings, particularly for this
youngest group aged 25-34, it must however be kept in mind that we are only able
to consider those in each age cohort living independently and not those who
remain in their family home. Eurostat figures suggest around one-in-four 25-34
year olds in Ireland live with their parents.
18
It is important to note that the homeownership simulations presented here are
based on the current market and regulatory conditions. In practice future
homeownership rates could be affected by various policy levers, a greater
provision of social and affordable housing, changes in the availability of policy
supports for homeownership, regulatory changes to private rental sector and
macroprudential regulations, as well as future economic conditions. It must also
be noted that the homeownership transitions that we model in this paper are
18
Available at:
https://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/databrowser/view/ILC_LVPS08__custom_2353321/default/table?lang=en.
Housing tenure and cost scenarios | 21
concerned solely with those relating to home purchase in the open market. We do
not consider any changes in tenure status that come about due to the inheritance
of whole (or substantial part) properties.
FIGURE 3.5 O
VERVIEW OF STATIC TENURE ASSIGNMENT METHOD
Source: Authorsanalysis.
Notes: We set LTV=90 per cent and LTi=3.5 in line with current macroprudential regulations for first-time buyers. d is down-payment;
Y
g
is gross household income; P
m
is the maximum potential monthly repayment (net income minus necessary expenditure);
r
s
is the prevailing interest rate for new mortgage loans plus 2 per cent; τ is the mortgage term set at the lower of either
30 years or the number of years until the household head reaches retirement age.
In the first stage of our assessment, we determine whether a household is high
credit-risk, and therefore unlikely to be able to pass a credit check and obtain a
mortgage at present. First, if the household head has been unemployed or inactive
in the labour market during the past 12 months. Second, we utilise a series of
indicators as a proxy for whether a household has a poor credit record. We
determine a household to be high credit risk if they had any rent, utilities or
consumer loan arrears in the past 12 months due to financial difficulties; state that
their existing debt
19
is a burden or that they are unable to meet an unexpected
expense; and also either face at least one deprivation indicator in SILC. Combining
these subjective measures of burden with more objective measures such as
deprivation indicators aims to capture those facing material difficulties because of
these burdens.
19
These households are in the rental sector and have no mortgage debt. Existing debt therefore refers to items such as
car loans, credit cards and other consumer loans.
22 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
In the second stage of our assessment, we use data on household income,
estimated savings that could be used as a down-payment, and expenditure to
assess whether they could pass the current regulatory hurdles regarding income,
wealth and affordability. Our methodology draws on the framework outlined in
Kelly et al. (2018) and McQuinn et al. (2021) by calculating three potential house
prices that a household could obtain given their gross income, estimated savings
and an affordability stress test.
Wealth
First-time buyers face a maximum Loan-to-Value (LTV) ratio of 90 per cent under
the current macroprudential mortgage regulations. The maximum house price
permissible under this LTV constraint is therefore d/1-LTV where d is the deposit.
We utilise detailed information on current income and expenditures to determine
what a household could reasonably be expected to accrue as a deposit. Specifically,
we allow a household to save three yearsworth
20
of any remainder from their net
monthly income after current rent and other minimum necessary expenditure. We
also model the likelihood a household receives an intergenerational wealth
transfer or gift. We allow 25 per cent of households to receive a 10,000 gift. This
choice of parameters is based on evidence on the prevalence and value of gift
giving from TILDA participants to their non-homeowning children (see Appendix
Table A.1). The findings from TILDA are consistent with evidence from the
Department of Housing, Local Government and Heritages survey of mature
homeowners (Corrigan, 2019) which found for mature homeowners providing gifts
to their children, the modal gift value was 10,000.
21
Income
First-time buyers face a maximum Loan-to-Income (LTI) ratio of 3.5
22
under the
current macroprudential mortgage regulations. Under this LTI constraint the
maximum house price is therefore 3.5 times gross income (i.e. maximum loan size)
plus deposit.
Affordability
Mortgage lenders perform a so-called affordability stress test on prospective
borrowers to ensure they would be able to continue to afford their mortgage
payments in the face of an interest rate rise. We therefore calculate the maximum
house price a household could afford in order to have sufficient residual income
after making mortgage payments to attain their minimum required expenditure if
they were faced with a 2 percentage point increase in the interest rate. We do so
using the amortisation formula outlined in Figure 3.5.
20
We choose three years based on the findings of Kelly and McCann (2016). The sensitivity of this choice is examined
further in Corrigan et al. (2020) Table 12.
21
The issue of more substantial inheritances is discussed in Section 3.3.3.
22
Up to 20 per cent of the value of FTB lending is permitted to be above this 3.5 LTI (Kinghan, 2018). In our sensitivity
analysis presented later in Table 3.1 we therefore increase the maximum permissible LTI to 4.5.
Housing tenure and cost scenarios | 23
If the lowest of these three house prices (i. wealth; ii. Income and iii. affordability)
is above the 25th percentile of the actual transacted house price distribution in the
households broad NUTS 3 region, then we determine they are likely to be able to
become homeowners. We choose the 25th percentile because Gaffney (2018)
finds that below this point the majority of transactions are by investors and cash
buyers rather than first-time buyers (see Table A.2 in Appendix II for further
details).
3.3.2 Tenure simulation results
Figure 3.6 presents the baseline results from our tenure simulations. The blue bars
correspond to the current percentage of each age band who are homeowners
(either outright or with a mortgage), while the red bars show the additional
proportion of each age group likely to be able to transition into homeownership
under the simulation methods outlined in Section 3.3.1. Homeownership rates for
those currently aged 65+ sit at 90 per cent. By definition we see no increase in
ownership rates for this group as the model does not permit mortgage borrowing
beyond retirement age. The findings from our simulations indicate that ownership
rates for the subsequent cohort, those aged 55-64, are 10 percentage points lower
and unlikely to rise any further. Ownership rates for the 45-54 cohort are expected
to be similar but marginally lower than for the 55-64 group, with simulations
suggesting an additional 2 per cent of this group could become owners, resulting
in an overall ownership rate of 79 per cent.
FIGURE 3.6 % HOMEOWNERS AFTER STATIC TENURE TRANSITION, BY AGE COHORT
Source: Authorscalculations using SILC 2018-2019.
0
10
20
30
40
50
60
70
80
90
100
25-34 35-44 45-54 55-64 65+
%
Owner - Actual Owner - Baseline Simulation
24 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
There is a marked fall in homeownership rates for the 35-44 cohort relative to the
45-54 group, with simulations suggesting a 65 per cent ownership rate for this
cohort, 14 percentage points below that of the previous age cohort. It is likely many
of this cohort will have been badly affected by the global financial crisis and
resulting changed credit access, as well as by the rapid house price and rental
growth observed since the mid-2010s. Focusing on our final group, those aged
25-34, we see a further substantial reduction, with the simulated homeownership
rate reaching just under 40 per cent. However, given the ages of this group, this
near-term assessment of their likelihood of being able to transition by home
purchase into homeownership is likely to significantly underestimate ownership
rates for this cohort across their lifetimes. We will return to this in Section 3.3.3.
Table 3.1 explores the constraints faced by current renters that do not transition
into homeownership in our simulations. At least two-thirds of these households in
each age cohort are determined to be high credit risk, suggesting they are unlikely
to be able to pass a credit check and obtain mortgage credit. The share of high
credit risk households rises with age, reaching nearly 84 per cent of non-
homeowners in the 55-64 cohort. More than half of these households in each age
cohort are unable to save any of their monthly income after paying their rent and
other essential expenditures. This inability to save is further highlighted by the fact
that more than 80 per cent of those unable to transition in the 25-34 and 35-44
cohorts have insufficient savings for the required down-payment (LTV
constrained).
TABLE 3.1 WHAT % OF NON-TRANSITIONERS ARE CONSTRAINED BY DIFFERENT FACTORS?
Constraining Factor
25-34
35-44
45-54
55-64
High credit risk 64.9 76.0 82.0 83.6
Zero or negative monthly savings
54.3
62.5
57.6
59.0
LTV constrained
81.2
81.6
71.8
71.3
LTI constrained
41.5
37.3
48.5
57.5
Affordability constrained
56.1
62.7
60.4
68.7
Source: Authorscalculations using SILC 2018-2019.
Note: Negative monthly savings refers to a situation where minimum necessary expenditure on essential goods exceeds the
households monthly disposable income.
Scenarios for potential credit access supports
The simulation modelling framework outlined in Section 3.3.1 applies strict credit
conditions based on current macroprudential regulations (see baseline scenario 1
in Table 3.2). As Table 3.1 shows, the majority of those unable to transition into
homeownership face insufficient down-payment constraints, while around two-in-
five are also constrained by the loan size relative to their income. Given the
importance of credit access conditions for household transitions, there is potential
Housing tenure and cost scenarios | 25
scope for policy support (both on the income and down-payment side) to
potentially aide households to become homeowners.
To explore the potential impact of easier credit access conditions, in addition to
our baseline scenario (scenario 1), we also deploy a number of illustrative scenarios
in Table 3.2 which attempt to capture the possible range of options that could be
used by Irish policymakers (such as instruments that would increase the income-
leverage ratio like local authority loans or shared-equity or deposit support
arrangements). We do not attempt to model any specific Irish policy instruments,
rather we attempt to deploy illustrative scenarios that capture the mechanisms by
which these measures would work. We deploy the following scenarios:
1. On the income side, we loosen the maximum LTI from 3.5 to 4.5 (scenario 2);
2. On the wealth side, we allow an equity, or down-payment support of €20,000
for all households
23
(scenario 3); and
3. Combine both (1) and (2) above (scenario 4).
Implicitly these scenarios assume an elastic housing supply i.e. that this additional
credit in the market would have no impact on house prices because housing supply
would adjust. In reality, in such a supply constrained housing market as the Irish
market, this is an unrealistic assumption. In scenarios 5-7 we therefore account for
the feedback loops between credit and house prices i.e. in each of the scenarios
deployed we take the estimated increase in credit extended and increase house
prices proportionately given an illustrative elasticity. We apply an elasticity of 0.15,
meaning that a one per cent increase in credit is associated with a 0.15 per cent
increase in house prices. This parameter is consistent with the international
findings of Favara and Imbs (2015), as well as McQuinn et al. (2021) who find
elasticities in the range 0.143-0.179 for Ireland (depending on the model
specification).
23
Note this is a simplified, illustrative exercise and, while its impact targets a similar channel, is not intended to mirror
current equity supports such as the Help-to-Buy scheme which is restricted to new build properties only and is only
available to those with sufficient prior tax contributions.
26 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
TABLE 3.2 HOMEOWNERSHIP RATE SIMULATIONS BY AGE COHORT (%) ADDITIONAL
SCENARIOS
Scenario
25-34
35-44
45-54
55-64
>65
Change from Baseline Scenario (1)
1
39.7
64.7
79.2
81.4
90.3
-
2
39.9
64.7
79.3
81.4
90.3
LTI
3 52.2 72.5 84.2 82.9 90.3 Equity support
4
54.8
73.7
85.0
83.3
90.3
LTI & equity support
5
39.9
64.7
79.3
81.4
90.3
LTI & feedback to house prices
6
48.8
70.5
83.0
82.7
90.3
Equity support & feedback to house prices
7
51.4
71.0
83.3
82.8
90.3
LTI & equity support & feedback to house prices
Source: Authorscalculations using SILC 2018 and 2019.
Note: Sensitivity scenario parameters: LTI increased from 3.5 to 4.5 for all; Equity support 20,000 towards savings for down-payment
(note this is a flat rate payment for all, not dependent on households tax contribution as current Help-to-Buy scheme); scenarios
5-7 take account of the impact increased credit has on house prices. To do so we use an elasticity of 0.15. This is consistent with
the findings for McQuinn et al. (2021) for Ireland who find the elasticity for Ireland ranges between 0.143-0.179 depending on the
model specification.
Homeownership rates in these additional scenarios remain similar to those
presented in Figure 3.6 for households aged 45 and over. This is consistent with
previous findings that homeownership rates level off after 40-45 (Corlett and
Judge, 2017; Roantree et al., 2021). Unsurprisingly there is more variation for the
35-44 and 25-34 cohorts. Focusing on scenarios 5-7, we see that providing
households with this significant down-payment support could raise the ownership
rates by 9 and 6 percentage points respectively for the 25-34 and 35-44 cohorts
(scenario 6). Solely increasing the multiple of income households can borrow has
minimal impact on the homeownership rate (scenario 5). This is not to say that LTI
constraints are not binding, but rather that LTV or wealth constraints are more
prevalent. Indeed, this is evident from scenario 7 where combining income and
down-payment supports further raises the homeownership rates, particularly for
the youngest 25-34 cohort. Nevertheless, even in the face of significant supports,
the homeownership rate for the 35-44 cohort would be expected to reach a
maximum of 71 per cent, remaining around 12 percentage points below that of the
previous 44-54 cohort under the same supports.
Even with these significant supports, ownership rates for the youngest cohort
remain substantially lower still at just over 50 per cent. However, given the ages of
this group, this near-term assessment of their likelihood of being able to transition
into homeownership is likely to underestimate ownership rates for this cohort
across their lifetimes. We will now examine this further.
3.3.3 25-34 cohort
The median age of first-time buyers in Ireland in 2019 was 34 (Gaffney and Kinghan,
2021). Many in their mid to late 20s and early 30s may therefore expect to see
significant career progression and therefore income growth before they attempt
to purchase a home. The near-term modelling approach outlined in Section 3.3.1
Housing tenure and cost scenarios | 27
is therefore arguably not suitable for the youngest cohort in our analysis.
To address this, in this section we transition households in the 25-34 age cohort
forwards ten years based on a series of growth rates outlined below. As above,
when interpreting our findings, it must be kept in mind that we are only able to
consider those in this age cohort living independently and not those who remain
in their family home.
In our baseline dynamic scenario we grow each households income forward based
on a sector-age-education growth rate matrix. Essentially this grows forward a
25-34 aged households income to the level of those with similar employment
sector and education profiles in the current 35-44 cohort.
24
In addition, we allow
house prices to grow at 5 per cent per year over this ten-year period (broadly in
line with long-run average house price growth), rental growth is capped at 2 per
cent annually as per current regulations in Rent Pressure Zones, and households
minimum necessary expenditures on other goods and services are assumed to
grow at 2 per cent per year, as are incomes (over and above the transformation
described above). We will examine the sensitivity of these parameter assumptions
below. In addition, we remove the current credit risk assessment outlined in
Section 3.3.1 as it is based on the current situation of the household and may
therefore not be relevant ten years into the future. Assumptions around the time
to accumulate a down-payment, the parameterisation of intergenerational wealth
transfers (gifts) and LTV/LTI requirements under the macroprudential measures for
first-time buyers remain unchanged from the framework outlined in Section 3.3.1.
We present the results of these simulations in Table 3.3. We do so both under
current macroprudential conditions (Baseline) and in the case of income and
down-payment supports, accounting for the likely impact of this on house prices
(LTI and equity support and feedback to house prices). Under these baseline
dynamic assumptions, our simulations suggest that 52 per cent of the 25-34 cohort
would be able to transition into homeownership in ten years time (Table 3.3,
scenario 2). This is significantly higher than the 39.7 per cent suggested by the near-
term static simulations for this cohort presented in Section 3.3.2 (also shown in
Table 3.3, scenario 1), but still notably lower than for previous age cohorts.
Combining income and down-payment supports whilst accounting for their likely
impact on house prices would further raise the homeownership rate to just over
55 per cent, 4 percentage points higher than for the equivalent near term static
scenario for this cohort (Table 3.2, scenario 7).
24
Specifically, we take the difference between the median income level for workers aged 25-34 and those aged 35-44 in
each NACE sector-education grouping. We then uprate household incomes for the 25-34 group by this difference to
bring their income levels in line with similar households in the 35-44 age group. On top of this, we allow their incomes
to grow 2 per cent per year over this ten-year period.
28 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
TABLE 3.3 HOMEOWNERSHIP RATE SIMULATIONS FOR 25-34 COHORT (%)
Scenario
Baseline
LTI & equity support &
feedback to house prices
Scenario Notes
1 39.7 51.4
Static (taken from Table 3.2 scenarios 1 (baseline) and
7 (LTI & equity support & feedback to house prices)
2
52.0 55.3
Dynamic
Sensitivity:
3
55.4
59.3
3% annual house price growth
4 48.6 52.5
House prices growing faster than incomes
(7% annual house price growth)
5 60.0 64.3
Uniform house price and income growth
(5% annual income growth for all)
6
51.7
55.3
4% annual rental price growth
7
48.5
51.8
8% annual rental price growth
8
52.0
55.4
Increase retirement age to 70
Source: Authorscalculations using SILC 2018-2019.
Note: Baseline: LTI 3.5; three years to save deposit; 25 per cent get €10,000 gift towards deposit; no current high credit risk filter; implicit
3.2 per cent average annual income growth; 2 per cent annual rental price growth; 5 per cent annual house price growth using
the 25th percentile (p(25)) house price sold in NUTS 3 area as threshold; minimum expenditures 2 per cent annual growth. In each
scenario we change one of these parameters from its baseline level. Scenarios 3-8 should be compared against scenario 2.
It must be noted that these figures should not be seen as maximum possible
achievable rates of homeownership for a number of reasons. This includes the
considerable uncertainty around projections concerning long-term income and
housing market dynamics, the impact of whole home inheritances and other policy
measures. Rather our scenarios should be seen as illustrative possible transition
likelihoods given the current household structure and different scenarios for
incomes, house prices and credit access. In the medium- to long-term, all of these
aspects can be impacted by policy changes.
Given the considerable uncertainty around the future paths of incomes, house
prices and rents used for projecting these householdssituation ten years into the
future, it is useful to understand how changing key parameters (and therefore the
relativities between them) would affect the likelihood of homeownership for
households currently aged 25-34.
Housing tenure and cost scenarios | 29
FIGURE 3.7 % HOMEOWNERS 25-34 COHORT DIFFERENT HOUSE PRICE AND INCOME GROWTH
SCENARIOS
(a) (b)
Source: Authorscalculations using SILC 2018-2019.
Note: Red bars represent baseline scenario (Table 3.3 Baseline column, scenario 2); blue bar represents Table 3.3 Baseline column,
scenario 3; green bar represents Table 3.3 Baseline column, scenario 4; purple bar represents Table 3.3 Baseline column,
scenario 5.
Figure 3.7a explores how the likelihood of homeownership changes when we alter
the rate of annual house price growth over the ten-year period, holding all other
parameters constant. In the blue bar we lower the annual house price growth to
3 per cent (down from 5 per cent in the baseline scenario). This results in the
homeownership rate rising by 3 percentage points to 55 per cent relative to the
baseline scenario. In the green bar we instead increase annual house price growth
to 7 per cent. This highlights the case where house price growth is significantly
more rapid than income growth. In this instance the ownership rate falls by
4 percentage points from the baseline scenario to 48 per cent.
In Figure 3.7b the purple bar illustrates a scenario where we instead allow all
incomes to grow at 5 per cent per year, in line with the 5 per cent annual house
price growth assumption. This contrasts to the baseline scenario where
householdsincome growth paths are determined individually depending on their
employment sector and education levels. Instead, here we see that if incomes and
house prices were to grow in line with each other for all households, the ownership
rate would increase by almost 8 percentage points to around 60 per cent. The
simulations presented in Figure 3.7 demonstrate the importance of the relative
growth rates of incomes and house prices (as well as how income growth is
distributed across households) in determining the homeownership rate for this
cohort.
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
55
60
Annual House Price Growth
% 25-34 Homeowners
3% Baseline (5%) 7%
20
25
30
35
40
45
50
55
60
Annual Income Growth
% 25-34 Homeowners
Baseline (Average 3.2%) 5% for all
30 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
The remainder of our sensitivity checks are presented in scenarios 6-8 in Table 3.3.
Increasing the annual rental price growth from 2 per cent to 4 per cent only has a
small negative impact on the ownership rate (scenario 6). This finding is likely
explained by the high level of rents relative to incomes for many households that
may prevent them from saving sufficiently for a deposit. Indeed, in the SILC data
we find just over one-in-three of the age 25-34 households are not currently able
to save anything on a monthly basis once they have paid their housing costs and
other essential expenditures. Significantly higher rental growth of 8 per cent per
year (scenario 7) would however have a more notable negative impact on
ownership rates. Increasing the retirement age for this cohort to 70 also has little
effect on the overall ownership rate (scenario 8). Increasing the retirement age
affects the affordability stress test by lengthening the available mortgage term.
However, as the majority of households are constrained by insufficient wealth or
income to overcome the LTV and LTI conditions, rather than solely by the
affordability stress test, this has a negligible effect on the overall homeownership
rate.
Regardless of the specific parameters chosen, the results in Table 3.3 clearly show
that the 25-34 cohort are likely to see significantly lower homeownership rates
relative to previous age cohorts. It is however important to keep in mind a number
of caveats when modelling homeownership rates for this youngest cohort. We are
only able to model households living independently with the required income,
housing costs and expenditure data, meaning that those living with parents or
family members are not included in the analysis.
25
Furthermore, given the dynamic
nature of this analysis and uncertainty around both how household incomes and
house prices are likely to develop, there is more uncertainty around the estimates
for this age group.
One major barrier to homeownership for younger age cohorts is the lack of long-
term job and earnings security (Lersch and Dewilde, 2015; Akdogan et al., 2019).
While we do not explicitly model this, analysis of the type of employment contract
for those we find could transition into homeownership confirms that this is largely
being captured implicitly in our simulation modelling framework.
One often mentioned potential mitigating factor for the fall in homeownership
rates observed for younger age cohorts is that of future inheritance (see above). In
25
It is unclear whether we would expect those remaining in the family home to have a higher or lower likelihood of
becoming homeowners relative to those living independently that we are able to model. On the one hand those living
with family may have more opportunities to save due to not making rent payments (or making smaller contributions
to the family) which could increase their likelihood of transition into homeownership. On the other hand, it could be
the case that many of those remaining in the family home do so because they have lower incomes and cannot afford
to live independently, which could make them less likely to transition.
Housing tenure and cost scenarios | 31
our model we parameterise parental gifts towards a deposit. However, we do not
model the inheritance of whole homes.
26
Rather our framework only estimates the
transitions related to market home purchases as noted above. The role future
inheritance will play in ownership rates for younger age groups is unclear. While
some households will benefit from inheriting an entire home, in practice there are
a number of reasons why we may not expect this to significantly counteract the
observed fall in homeownership in younger age cohorts. First, international
evidence suggests that inheritance tends to amplify inequality within generations,
i.e. between those with richer and those with poorer parents (Bourquin et al.,
2021). This suggests that many of those in a position to inherit a family home will
have already received parental gifts towards a deposit. In contrast, those who
remain non-homeowners at a later age are those less likely to receive a substantial
inheritance. Second, given current life expectancy, it is quite likely that many
recipients may inherit in their 50s and 60s, past the age at which mortgaged
homeownership is typically feasible. If any inheritance was therefore insufficient
to purchase a home outright, such as in the case of several siblings receiving an
equal share, these households would likely struggle to obtain mortgage credit and
transition into homeownership at that point. Despite these caveats, it is possible
that the homeownership rate for renters would rise if explicit modelling of this
potential inheritance channel were to be conducted.
3.4 SUMMARY
The aims of this chapter were to examine current housing tenure and cost patterns
for different age cohorts and to simulate the likelihood that households will
become homeowners. To do so we used the ESRIs Affordability and Tenure
Housing Microsimulation Engine (AT-HOME) tool to simulate the likelihood of
current rental households in different age cohorts being able to transition to
homeownership under a prudent credit risk assessment policy and current market
conditions and regulations.
Our findings show the current retirement cohort have very high rates of
homeownership (90 per cent) and therefore very low levels of housing costs. In
addition, the majority of non-homeowners in this cohort are in the supported
rental sector, either living in local authority provided accommodation or housed in
private sector accommodation and in receipt of housing supports. On average
housing cost-to-income ratios are significantly higher in the private rental sector
than other tenures. For those below the age of 55, while mortgaged households
typically pay no more than 20-21 per cent on average, private renters not in receipt
of housing supports in the youngest cohort (25-34) as well as those aged 45-54 are
on average paying 27 per cent of their incomes on rent.
26
Future research which can incorporate this into the framework would be a natural extension to this research.
32 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
Relative to current pensioners, homeownership rates are around 10 percentage
points lower for the subsequent 55-64 and 45-54 age cohorts and are unlikely to
rise further for these groups. Moreover, our simulations based on current market
and regulatory conditions would suggest a further significant decline in
homeownership rates for younger cohorts. Our baseline estimates suggest around
two-thirds of those aged 35-44 are likely to become homeowners and only 52 per
cent of those aged 25-34. While combining an equity support towards a down-
payment and loosening the amount households can borrow relative to their
incomes would boost these cohorts homeownership rates, they remain
significantly below those of previous cohorts.
A number of caveats must be kept in mind when interpreting these findings. Our
simulations are based on current market and regulatory conditions. Ownership
rates for younger cohorts are sensitive to future economic and regulatory
conditions. In particular, we show that estimates are most sensitive to future house
price and income growth and the relativities between them. Furthermore, there
are levers which could help to alleviate such stark declines in homeownership rates
for younger cohorts, particularly a large-scale increase in the supply of affordable
housing both in the owner occupation sector and the rental sector which could
facilitate the accrual of deposits.
One limitation of our model is that households are assessed on their ability to
purchase a home within their current NUTS 3 region. For those in Dublin facing the
highest house prices, this could be a restrictive assumption as in practice they may
be able to purchase in a neighbouring area. However, while this may on the one
hand work to increase homeownership, it could also likely drive up prices in those
areas, which could then crowd out those currently living in those areas.
Income adequacy in retirement | 33
CHAPTER 4
Income adequacy in retirement
4.1 INTRODUCTION
The previous chapter clearly outlined the expected fall in homeownership in
younger age cohorts for Ireland over the coming years. The lower rate of
homeownership will naturally lead to a greater share of the population paying
housing costs into retirement (relative to the natural mortgage amortisation
process that occurs for homeowners). The critical question remains as to the extent
to which these households will face income inadequacy given that housing costs
remain part of their monthly expenditure.
Previous research by Beirne et al. (2020) assessed the income adequacy of those
who were approaching retirement (born 1955-1960) by calculating income poverty
rates on a before housing costs basis. The analysis identified a number of groups
who were already vulnerable to income poverty on this basis, and it is likely that
these and additional groups may face additional challenges if potential housing
costs in retirement are taken into account.
The aim of this chapter is to attempt to assess the scale of this challenge. We use
an augmented version of TRIAM (the ESRI model of income adequacy in retirement
developed by Beirne et al. (2020) based on TILDA, the Irish Longitudinal Study on
Ageing) to calculate after housing costs measures of income poverty for a) the
current cohort of those approaching retirement (i.e. those born 1955-1960) and b)
future cohorts of retirees (by adjusting the homeownership rates of the current
cohort of retirees to reflect projected homeownership rates of future cohorts with
reference to the range of homeownership scenarios outlined in Chapter 3).
4.2 DATA AND METHODOLOGY
For this analysis, we follow Beirne et al. (2020) in using the main TILDA dataset; a
nationally representative survey of community-dwelling individuals aged 50 years
and over, and their spouses or partners of any age (i.e. individuals living in nursing
homes or other institutions were excluded at baseline). The survey is harmonised
with other international longitudinal studies of ageingsuch as the US Health and
Retirement Study (HRS), the Survey of Health, Ageing and Retirement in Europe
(SHARE) and the English Longitudinal Study on Ageing (ELSA) and contains rich
information on the demographic, health and socio-economic circumstances of
older people in Ireland. Data are collected primarily via computer-aided personal
interviewing (CAPI). Data collection for the first wave took place over the period
34 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
October 2009 to February 2011, when 8,504 individuals were sampled, of whom
8,175 were aged 50+ years (Barrett et al., 2011).
27
TRIAM simulates future disposable after tax and welfare payments, but before
housing costs (BHC) income in retirement for the sample who were born between
1955 and 1960 (i.e. those aged between 50 and 55 at TILDA Wave 1, who are
expected to reach the state pension age between 2022 and 2027).
28
The model is
described in detail by Beirne et al. (2020). We use detailed information on
employment history, income, wealth, pension cover and family status, collected in
TILDA Wave 1 in 2010, along with assumptions about likely income and asset
growth rates,
29
to simulate future disposable income at the point of retirement. In
this report, we augment these simulations by incorporating an after housing costs
(AHC) measure of disposable income in retirement. The housing costs we deduct
from disposable income are zero for those who own their house outright, which is
the vast majority of the sample, and equal to rents private or social for renters.
The TILDA data do not allow us to distinguish mortgage capital and interest
repayments, so for the very small share of homeowners who do not expect to own
their dwelling outright at the point of retirement we include both payments.
30
Following the approach of Crawford and ODea (2012), we consider alternate
definitions of income which differ in their treatment of assets accumulated before
retirement. Our first definition, which we refer to as narrow income, is that
derived from the public and private pensions of household members and market
income of spouses who are still in work, less applicable direct taxes. The second
adds to this income from financial assets, or more specifically the annuitised value
of net financial assets (excluding owner-occupied but including holiday or
investment property). Where the individual is a member of a couple, incomes of
both partners are considered and total household income is adjusted (equivalised)
for household size.
31
To assess the adequacy of income in retirement we adopt a poverty-line approach
that conceives of income adequacy as related to the surpassing the minimum
27
Further information on the sample design is available elsewhere (e.g. Whelan and Savva, 2013).
28
A number of these individuals reported being retired at the time of the 2010 TILDA survey (n=58). We drop these from
our sample leaving a final sample size of 1,904.
29
Tables A1.1 and A1.2 in Beirne et al. (2020) detail the various growth rate assumptions used in the model.
30
This differs from the definition of housing costs used by both Eurostat and the CSO, which also includes insurance, light
and heat (information on which are not reliably available in TILDA), but excludes capital repayments. Given these
represent the bulk of repayments towards the end of a mortgage, their inclusion means that we are likely overstating
housing costs in retirement for a very small share of our sample.
31
We use the national (CSO) equivalence scale, which gives the first adult in a household a weight of 1, subsequent adults
aged 14+ a weight of 0.66 and any children a weight of 0.33.
Income adequacy in retirement | 35
resources needed to buy essential goods and services.
32
What should be
considered an essential good or service is ultimately a subjective question and will
naturally evolve over time. We therefore examine three related measures that
form part of policy discussions both in Ireland and abroad, namely living in a
household with less than 60, 50 or 40 per cent of median equivalised disposable
household income. These thresholds correspond to those used for the national at-
risk-of-poverty (AROP) line (60 per cent), the OECD AROP line (50 per cent), and
what is sometimes called the severeAROP line (40 per cent).
33
4.3 RESULTS AND EMPIRICAL FINDINGS
Table 4.1 presents these AROP measures on a before (BHC) and after (AHC) housing
costs basis for our baseline simulations, i.e. using respondentsrecorded housing
tenure, which corresponds to a 92 per cent homeownership rate for our current
cohort of TILDA retirees. We also present AROP measures on an AHC basis for the
sample given three sets of homeownership scenarios (high, medium and low) of:
78 per cent (high scenario);
70 per cent (medium scenario); and
63 per cent (low scenario).
The calibration of these scenarios is informed by the analysis in Chapter 3. As our
approach uses data on the cohort currently approaching retirement, we explore a
set of plausible scenarios that attempt to cover a range of likely homeownership
rates presented in Chapter 3 (Table 3.2). As there was considerable variation across
the age specific cohorts in Chapter 3, we chose a set of parameter values that
attempt to provide an informed range of possible homeownership levels that
capture the range in the baseline scenario for the groups aged 35-44 and 45-54 of
64.7 and 79 per cent).
34
We do not model a scenario lower than 63 per cent (such
as those for the youngest age category in Chapter 3) given the considerable
uncertainty around this cohort.
The scenarios are modelled by first estimating the relationship between a set of
household characteristics and the likelihood of transitioning to homeowner status
in AT-HOME. These estimates are then used to predict the probability of
homeownership for our TILDA sample given the same set of characteristics. We
then simulate rental costs for the 14 per cent (high scenario), 22 per cent (medium
32
There is a large literature in Ireland on the problems with relying on income poverty alone to assess living standards
(Fahey et al., 2004b). However, we do not have the required information in TILDA to be able to calculate measures of
deprivation, and by extension, consistent poverty.
33
See, for example, Brewer et al. (2010). These measures are set with reference to population-wide AHC or BHC median
income as recorded in the 2017 Survey on Income and Living Conditions, with nominal figures uprated to expected
retirement date by the same factor as earnings (forecast wage growth).
34
The scenarios modelled here do not map precisely onto those presented in Table 3.2 due to small discontinuities in the
distribution of homeownership probabilities described below. As a result, 78 per cent is the closest calibration to 79 per
cent that we can model, and likewise 63 per cent the closest calibration to 64.7 per cent.
36 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
scenario) and 29 (low scenario) per cent of respondents with the lowest predicted
probability of homeownership, assigning them the median regional rent observed
for similarly aged renters in TILDA. We finally deduct these housing costs from
disposable BHC income to give our simulated AHC income in retirement.
35
Our
assessment of after housing costs poverty is based on a definition of housing costs
that includes just rent payments (we assume all homeowners in TILDA have repaid
their mortgage by the SPA). It therefore does not take into account other
maintenance, insurance, etc. costs associated with housing.
36
TABLE 4.1 POVERTY LINE (AROP) MEASURES OF INCOME ADEQUACY
(%)
(%)
(%)
Share with income in retirement that is:
<60% median
<50% median
<40% median
A. Baseline simulations (BHC):
Narrow
24.4
7.1
3.1
Plus annuitised value of net financial assets
9.2
3.0
1.4
B. Baseline simulations (AHC):
Narrow
28.1
12.2
6.3
Plus annuitised value of net financial assets
14.1
7.9
3.9
C. High homeownership scenario (AHC):
Narrow
38.7
20.9
8.2
Plus annuitised value of net financial assets
23.6
14.1
4.6
D. Medium homeownership scenario (AHC):
Narrow
42.8
24.7
8.9
Plus annuitised value of net financial assets
27.8
16.7
4.6
E. Low homeownership scenario (AHC):
Narrow
47.2
28.3
9.6
Plus annuitised value of net financial assets
31.4
19.1
4.8
Source: Authorscalculations using data from the Irish Longitudinal Study of Ageing (TILDA).
Note: Median equivalised income for poverty lines taken from 2017 Survey on Income and Living Conditions, uprated to expected
retirement date by forecast wage growth.
Panel A in Table 4.1 shows that for our baseline simulation using the narrow
definition of income, 24.4 per cent of those approaching the SPA are likely to have
income below the 60 per cent AROP line on a BHC basis. This rate falls to 9.2 per
cent when one uses the broader measure of income that includes the annuitised
value of net financial assets, which Beirne et al. (2020) show play an important role
in individualspreparedness for retirement. The share likely to fall below the 50
and 40 per cent AROP lines is by definition lower but substantially so, at 3 per
cent and 1.4 per cent respectively using our broader measure of income. This
35
We also examined results using a different approach where rents were set at 20 per cent of (BHC) incomes before
retirement and remained at that (real) level into retirement. These provided similar results to those presented in
Table 4.1.
36
See Fahey et al. (2004b) for a discussion of the limitations of using before and after housing costs measures to assess
income poverty. The after housing costs income poverty measure ignores the fact that people on a similar income may
simply make different choices about how much to spend on housing versus other goods and services: higher housing
expenditure may be associated with higher-quality housing.
Income adequacy in retirement | 37
illustrates the sizeable share of individuals in our baseline simulation with incomes
of between 50 and 60 per cent of median equivalised income.
Panel B shows the income adequacy measures for this group on an AHC, rather
than BHC, basis. The AROP rates are higher in all instances, rising from 9.2 per cent
to 14.1 per cent using the broader definition of income under the 60 per cent AROP
threshold, and from 1.4 to 3.9 per cent under the 40 per cent threshold. This
relatively muted rise in AROP rates reflects the 92 per cent homeownership rate in
our baseline simulation, with the vast majority of these facing housing costs of
zero.
However, AROP rates are substantially higher on an AHC basis when we
incorporate lower expected homeownership rates. Panel C shows that using our
broader measure of income, 23.6 per cent are likely to fall below 60 per cent AROP
line in retirement under the high-homeownership scenario of 78 per cent
compared to 14.1 per cent in our baseline.
Panels D and E show that the medium- and low-homeownership scenarios result
in even higher AROP rates of 27.8 and 31.4 per cent respectively using the
broader definition of income and the 60 per cent AROP line. Both are around
double the AROP rate in the baseline (14.1 per cent AROP assuming a 92 per cent
homeownership rate) homeownership scenario, and illustrate the potential
impacts being exposed to even modest housing costs can have on the adequacy of
income in retirement. Similarly, our simulations for AROP rates using the broader
definition of income and the 50 per cent threshold are at least double the baseline
rate of 7.9 per cent in the medium- and low-homeownership scenarios, and almost
double even in the high-homeownership scenario.
While the severeAROP rate is also higher in the simulated homeownership
scenarios than the baseline, the increase is much more muted than for the national
(60 per cent) and OECD (50 per cent) AROP lines. This is because the distribution
of AHC income is particularly dense around 50-60 per cent of the median (i.e.
around the national and OECD AROP line), with most households brought beneath
the national or OECD AROP line by housing costs not brought significantly below it.
38 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
TABLE 4.2 POVERTY GAP FOR VARIOUS MEASURES OF INCOME ADEQUACY
(%)
(%)
(%)
Poverty gap for:
<60% median
<50% median
<40% median
Baseline Before Housing Costs (BHC) results:
Narrow
16.5
21.9
25.2
Plus annuitised value of net financial assets
18.7
35.4
59.6
Baseline After Housing Costs (AHC) results:
Narrow 22.0 27.1 31.2
Plus annuitised value of net financial assets
27.0
30.7
42.6
High homeownership scenario:
Narrow
22.4
20.9
29.3
Plus annuitised value of net financial assets
24.2
21.5
40.3
Medium homeownership scenario:
Narrow
22.6
19.0
28.1
Plus annuitised value of net financial assets
22.8 18.3 39.1
Low homeownership scenario:
Narrow
22.5
17.8
26.5
Plus annuitised value of net financial assets
22.3
16.9
37.6
Source: Authorscalculations using data from the Irish Longitudinal Study of Ageing (TILDA).
Note: Median equivalised income for poverty lines taken from 2017 Survey on Income and Living Conditions, uprated to expected
retirement date by forecast wage growth.
This is confirmed by Figure A.1 in the Appendix (which plots the distribution of AHC
income in our baseline and simulated homeownership scenarios), and by looking
at estimates of the poverty gap (the average distance from the poverty line for
those beneath the poverty line, expressed as a percentage of the poverty line).
Estimates of the poverty gap are shown in Table 4.2 for the various poverty line
measures we consider. The key result to note is that estimates of the poverty gap
are almost all smaller in our lower homeownership scenarios than in our baseline
AHC simulations. In other words, while the share of the population beneath the
poverty line is higher under each of our simulated homeownership rate scenarios,
those underneath those lines are beneath by less. Although our focus in this paper
is on poverty line measures of income adequacy, Figure A.1 also shows that lower
rates of homeownership have a substantial impact on the distribution of AHC
income across the distribution. This reflects the fact that lower future rates of
homeownership are likely to reduce the level of AHC resources available to
households, by exposing those renting to higher levels of housing costs in
retirement.
Finally, we turn to look at which groups of individuals are at greater risk of being
below the various poverty lines. Table 4.3 displays the odds ratios from logistic
regressions of individual characteristics on the probability of having disposable
income in retirement below the 60 per cent AROP line on both a BHC basis
(Column 1) and an AHC basis (Column 2). These are for our baseline simulations
(i.e. correspond to the estimates in Panels A and B of Tables 4.1 and 4.2) using the
Income adequacy in retirement | 39
more broadly defined measure of income.
37
Odds ratios are best explained with an
example. An odds ratio of 2 says that an individual in group A faces twice the
chance of someone in the excluded group B of having an inadequate income in
retirement.
38
The key information to take from Table 4.3 is whether the coefficient
is above or below 1, indicating that an individual with a certain characteristic (e.g.
being a woman) has respectively a greater or lower chance of having inadequate
income in retirement than a similar individual in the excluded category (in this
example, a man).
The odds ratios show that men, individuals with higher levels of education and
those living in a farming household are less likely to have incomes below the 60 per
cent AROP line on both a BHC and an AHC basis, though the last of these estimates
is not statistically significant on a BHC basis at the 95 per cent level of confidence.
Nor is there any statistically significant relationship between the region of
residence and the likelihood of being below the AROP line. However, perhaps the
most striking result is that while there is no statistically significant association
between being single in working life and being below the 60 per cent AROP line in
retirement on a BHC basis (conditional on other factors), there is an extremely
strong and statistically significant association on an AHC basis. This aligns with the
findings of previous research that those living alone are particularly vulnerable to
having inadequate resources in retirement, with our results suggesting that such
concerns might be even more pronounced after one accounts for housing costs
(Nolan et al., 2019; Beirne et al., 2020).
37
Table A.3 in Appendix II presents similar models for the narrowdefinition of income.
38
These allow us to easily compare the relative chance that someone in each group has of having inadequate income in
retirement (which is constant across other covariates), but do not allow the absolute or relative risk of income
adequacy to be directly inferred (as these depend on the values taken by other covariates).
40 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
TABLE 4.3 LOGISTIC REGRESSION OF THE FACTORS ASSOCIATED WITH AROP STATUS, BASELINE
SIMULATIONS, BROADER INCOME MEASURE
(1)
(2)
Share with income in retirement that is:
< 60% median BHC
< 60% median AHC
Living in
Dublin (reference)
Urban area outside Dublin
0.954
0.918
Rural area
1.005
0.760
Household type
Non-farming household (reference)
Farming household
0.502
0.447**
Cohabitation status in working life
Married/cohabitating (reference)
Single
0.891
5.714***
Gender
Man (reference)
Woman
1.531
*
1.429**
Education
Primary or lower (reference)
Lower secondary
0.779
0.515***
Upper secondary
0.595
*
0.321***
Post-secondary < degree
0.438
**
0.265***
Post-secondary degree or higher
0.287
***
0.132***
Observations
1,904
1,904
Source: Authorscalculations using data from the Irish Longitudinal Study of Ageing (TILDA).
Note: Coefficients show odds ratios from logistic regressions. Stars show statistical significance, indicating a p value of < 0.05 (*), < 0.01
(**) and < 0.001 (***) respectively.
4.4 SUMMARY
The results of this modelling exercise highlight the potential scale of the challenge
in ensuring that future cohorts of retirees will have adequate resources for their
retirement. The current cohort of those approaching retirement (born 1955-1960)
has high homeownership rates (above 90 per cent), which means that the
projected increases in the AROP rate for this cohort when housing costs are taken
into account are relatively muted. For example, using the broader definition of
income and the 60 per cent of median income AROP threshold, the AROP rate rises
from 9.2 per cent to 14.1 per cent. However, as detailed in Chapter 3, younger
cohorts are likely to have substantially lower homeownership rates. Based on the
modelling conducted in Chapter 3, assessments of AROP rates assuming alternative
homeownership rates of 78, 70 and 63 per cent results in higher AROP rates. Under
the high-homeownership scenario of 78 per cent, 23.6 per cent are likely to fall
below the 60 per cent AROP line in retirement. The medium- and low-
homeownership scenarios result in even higher AROP rates of 27.8 and 31.4 per
cent respectively; around double the AHC rate for those currently approaching
retirement.
Income adequacy in retirement | 41
The results of this research highlight the additional vulnerabilities in terms of
poverty risks that are likely to occur in Ireland with lower homeownership rates.
As more households have to carry housing costs in the form of rental payments
into retirement, this will increase the proportion of households at risk of poverty
and pose challenges to the pensions architecture. It is possible that these
assessments represent a lower bound on possible effects. The assessments of
income poverty using the TRIAM model in this chapter assume that future cohorts
of retirees will have similar characteristics to those who are currently approaching
retirement (i.e. born 1955-1960). This was done in order to isolate the impact of
projected changes in homeownership rates and housing costs on the retirement
income adequacy of future cohorts of retirees. However, it is likely that future
cohorts of retirees are likely to have different employment histories, savings
profiles, living arrangements, etc. than the current cohort, which in turn may affect
their risk of income poverty in retirement. For example, higher rental costs in early
to mid-adulthood may affect the capacity of future generations to build up the
same level of financial assets as the current cohort of retirees. The next chapter
draws out the implications of these and related issues for policy.
Conclusions | 43
CHAPTER 5
Conclusions
5.1 SUMMARY OF MAIN FINDINGS
As house prices and rents have risen sharply in recent years, Irelands housing
market has been characterised as having acute affordability challenges for cohorts
of the population, particularly low-to-moderate income urban renters. A defining
feature of the housing market since 2011 is a declining share of homeowners (in
particular mortgaged homeowners). While this of course contributes to
affordability challenges at present, the fall in homeownership also has important
implications for the provision of pensions and income adequacy in retirement. The
existing Irish pension system (and welfare state) has been geared towards high
homeownership which both lowers housing costs payments and raises asset values
for retirement consumption (Norris, 2016). Lower homeownership naturally
means a higher proportion of households in the rental sector and the continuation
of rental payments past the income retirement cliff without the security of the
family home asset.
This research attempts to consider a range of possible scenarios to quantify the
likely share of homeowners in the population going forward and then to explore
the likely impact of these homeownership rates on income adequacy for retired
households. Under a range of scenarios which vary savings levels (down-
payments), incomes, house prices, and credit access conditions, we find that the
rate of homeownership is likely to be considerably lower for future age cohorts
than current retirees. Our results suggest that a considerably higher proportion of
households aged under 45 will be renting come retirement than in previous
generations. While over 90 per cent of the current cohort of retirees are
homeowners, our baseline estimates suggest that around two-thirds of those aged
35-44 are likely to become homeowners through home purchase in the open
market and, with much greater uncertainty, we estimate only 52 per cent of those
aged 25-34. While combining an equity support towards a down-payment and
loosening the amount households can borrow relative to their incomes may boost
these cohorts homeownership rates, they are projected to remain significantly
below those of previous cohorts. However, projecting the likely homeownership
rates in retirement of the current 25-34 age cohort is particularly difficult as this
age cohort may be expected to experience further career progression and income
growth in the period during which homeownership typically occurs (up to age 45).
Using the current group of individuals who are nearing retirement as an
illustration, our results suggest that these projected falls in homeownership will be
associated with a rise in poverty rates on an after housing costs basis given current
44 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
income levels. For example, while 14 per cent of current retirees are at risk of
poverty on an after housing costs basis (using the official 60 per cent of median
income threshold and a broad definition of income), this proportion could be as
high as 31 per cent under the lowest homeownership rate scenario examined.
There are a number of limitations to our analysis that are important to point out.
First, our housing simulations are based on currently-formed households. Broadly
this can be considered a static style modelling approach in that it uses data on the
incomes, employment characteristics, expenditures and housing costs of existing
households and therefore does not focus on household formation or more
dynamic demographic changes that will undoubtedly impact the housing market
over time.
Second, while we do allow for intergenerational wealth transfers, we do not model
explicitly the inheritance of full homes. If whole homes were to be inherited by
renters, this could raise the homeownership rate above the level in our scenarios
of home purchase only. However, previous research (e.g. Lawless and Lynch, 2017)
shows that the receipt of such inheritances is positively associated with
beneficiaries own level of income. As transitioning to a homeowner in our
approach is more likely for higher income households (McQuinn et al., 2021), this
evidence suggests the inclusion of whole home inheritances would be unlikely to
substantially improve the homeownership prospects of those we model as
remaining renters into retirement.
Third, it is important to note that the homeownership simulations presented here
are based on the current market and regulatory conditions. In practice future
homeownership rates could be affected by various policy levers, a greater
provision of social and affordable housing, changes in the availability of policy
supports for homeownership, regulatory changes to private rental sector and
macroprudential regulations, as well as future economic conditions. The most
important economic determinant of our scenarios is the relative growth rate of
house prices versus incomes; if real income growth was faster than real house price
growth for a period this would facilitate a greater likelihood of homeownership.
However, for such a dynamic to occur it would mean demand-side factors (such as
income growth and demographics) would have to be outweighed by supply-side
influences in the housing market and would require a reversal of supply-demand
imbalances that are observed in the market at present.
Finally, the assessments of income poverty using the TRIAM model assume that
future cohorts of retirees will have similar characteristics to those who are
currently approaching retirement (i.e. born 1955-1960). This was done in order to
Conclusions | 45
isolate the impact of projected changes in homeownership rates and housing costs
on the retirement income adequacy of future cohorts of retirees. However, it is
likely that future cohorts of retirees are likely to have different employment
histories, savings profiles, living arrangements, etc. than the current cohort, which
in turn may affect their risk of income poverty in retirement. For example, higher
rental costs in early to mid-adulthood may affect the capacity of future generations
to build up the same level of financial assets as the current cohort of retirees.
5.2 POLICY IMPLICATIONS
Given the multifaceted nature of the problem of managing housing costs through
the income retirement shock, it is important to consider how policy can best adapt
to the likely lower structural rate of homeownership for future cohorts of retirees.
Policymakers attempting to consider the optimal policy mix to ensure adequate
income in retirement might consider the policy options as targeting the housing
costs element and the income adequacy element.
On the one hand, policies could be targeted to either improve incomes in older
households or to support renting households to build up more retirement
resources earlier in their lifecycle while in employment where possible. In the
former case, the approach would be to support the incomes of future retirees to a
greater extent so that even after accounting for higher expected housing costs,
incomes are sufficient to keep most above the poverty line. One way this could be
done is through increases in the maximum rates of the state pension above and
beyond that needed to keep track with earnings. However, the trade-off between
income support and fiscal cost efficiency would need to be considered here as such
an approach could be very expensive and would likely have considerable
deadweight given its untargeted nature. Furthermore, this approach may not be
fiscally sustainable in the context of the broader demographic pressures (Irish
Fiscal Advisory Council, 2020).
39
Another more targeted option could be to direct the additional income support to
those households for whom the income adequacy challenge is most acute. Our
results suggest that those living alone (during working life) are at even greater risk
of having inadequate income in retirement on an AHC basis than those who are
married or cohabiting. This is a group who already experience a much greater risk
of poverty, even before housing costs are considered. A bespoke instrument for
such a group, for example through an enhanced living alone allowance, offers one
more targeted option than broader-based increases in the state pension for all.
39
The population aged 65-79 is projected to grow by 88 per cent and the 80+ population by 240 per cent over the period
2020-2050 (with a consequent increase in the old-age dependency ratio from 22 to 47 per cent). Assuming current
policies, public spending on pensions is projected to increase from 7.7 per cent of GNI* to 11.9 per cent of GNI* over
the same period (Irish Fiscal Advisory Council, 2020).
46 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
However, this approach still may be fiscally costly and shifts the entire risk onto
future taxpayers with implications for intergenerational equity.
The second area of intervention that shifts the housing costs risk in retirement is
to directly intervene for households with housing costs challenges. At the point of
retirement this could be achieved by a targeted instrument such as an income
supplement or rent subsidy to directly cover housing costs for those households
who are proven to be in housing costs distress. However, the availability of, and
even the signalling of, such instruments could alter the incentives for households
to accumulate sufficient resources earlier in their working lives and potentially
expose the Exchequer to significant cost.
As incomes fall on retirement, many households would likely qualify for existing
supports such as HAP. However, Doolan et al. (2022) highlight the challenges
associated with this increased reliance on the private rental sector to house those
in receipt of housing supports. They show low levels of available properties under
scheme rent limits, particularly for high-risk groups such as single adult
households. Where rent limits do not keep pace with market rents, tenants face
the prospect of making additional top-up payments to landlords thus exposing
them to market forces, which is particularly problematic for retirees on fixed
incomes. Furthermore, such extensive supports for those living in private sector
accommodation risks fuelling rental inflation and the costs are likely to be
prohibitively expensive for the State given the scale of the projected fall in
homeownership for future retirement cohorts. Over and above the cost
implications of renting in retirement, another crucial aspect is the potential for
instability of tenure at a vulnerable stage in the lifecycle. This would be a
particularly prominent concern for those in private sector rather than local
authority accommodation.
Finally, considerations on the rate of homeownership, and implicitly for house
prices and rents, going forward are affected by many intertwined macroeconomic
and housing market factors. Policy interventions at earlier stages of the lifecycle
are critical to help lower the costs of housing that future cohorts will face in
retirement. Increased supply and other housing policy interventions can impact the
share of homeowners, while increased direct provision of social housing or policies
which develop alternative, non-market renting cohorts such as cost rental which
can all help to lower the cost of housing at retirement. In particular, if rents in cost
rental properties grow at a slower pace than incomes over time, this lowers the
affordability burden.
Conclusions | 47
More generally, the uncertainties attached to the timeframe in any longer-term
assessment of housing tenure and income adequacy in retirement would suggest
that rather than attempting to calibrate individual measures in the short term, a
longer-term policy planning exercise should be undertaken. This should consider a
suite of options and a range of policy levers that could be initiated depending on
the path which homeownership and poverty rates take. Indeed, given the general
challenges around ageing and pension provision (Irish Fiscal Advisory Council,
2020), it is unlikely the State will be able to fully carry the cost burden for the
challenge of higher housing costs in retirement. Therefore developing a policy
strategy which mixes lifetime incentives to accumulate retirement assets during
employment with an adequate safety net is most likely to be required. Further
research, on the sensitivity of projections of income adequacy to alternative
assumptions about work, pension and family structure throughout working life; on
the relative costs and benefits of alternative policy responses; and on comparable
policy responses in other countries, would help to tease out the appropriate policy
mix in the Irish context.
References | 49
REFERENCES
Akdogan, K., E. Karacimen and A.A. Yavuz (2019). Cross-country evidence on the link
between job security and housing credit’, Journal of Housing and the Built
Environment, 34(4), pp. 947-963.
Arundel, R. and J. Doling (2017). The end of mass homeownership? Changes in labour
markets and housing tenure opportunities across Europe’, Journal of Housing and
the Built Environment, 32(4), pp. 649-672.
Banks, J., C. Emmerson, Z. Oldfield and G. Tetlow (2005). Prepared for Retirement? The
Adequacy and Distribution of Retirement Resources in England. Institute for Fiscal
Studies.
Barrett, A., G. Savva, V. Timonen and R. Kenny (2011). Fifty Plus in Ireland 2011. The Irish
Longitudinal Study on Ageing, Dublin.
Beirne, K., A. Nolan and B. Roantree (2020). Income Adequacy in Retirement: Evidence
from the Irish Longitudinal Study on Ageing (TILDA). ESRI Research Series Report
No. 107, Economic and Social Research Institute: Dublin.
https://doi.org/10.26504/rs107.
Bercholz, M., A. Bergin, T. Callan, A. Garcia Rodriguez and C. Keane (2019). A micro-
macro economic analysis of pension auto-enrolment options’. Working Paper No.
640. Economic and Social Research Institute: Dublin.
Bergin, A. and A. Garcia-Rodriguez (2020). Regional demographics and structural housing
demand at a county level. ESRI Research Series Report No. 111. Economic and
Social Research Institute: Dublin. https://doi.org/10.26504/rs111.
Bourquin, P., R. Joyce and D. Sturrock (2021). Inheritances and inequality over the life
cycle: what will they mean for younger generations? (No. R188). IFS Report.
Bradbury, B. and P. Saunders (2021). Housing costs and poverty: Analysing recent
Australian trends’, Journal of Housing and the Built Environment.
https://doi.org/10.1007/s10901-021-09899-w.
Brewer, M., D. Philips and L. Siebieta (2010). What has happened to severe poverty
under Labour? Institute for Fiscal Studies. https://ifs.org.uk/bns/bn90.pdf.
Central Statistics Office (2017). Census of Population 2016Profile 1 Housing in Ireland.
CSO. https://www.cso.ie/en/releasesandpublications/ep/p-cp1hii/cp1hii/.
Central Statistics Office (2021a). Pension Coverage 2020. Central Statistics Office.
Central Statistics Office (2021b). Survey on Income and Living Conditions (SILC) 2020.
Central Statistics Office. https://www.cso.ie/en/releasesandpublications/ep/p-
silc/surveyonincomeandlivingconditionssilc2020/.
Coffey, C., P.J. Hogan, C. O’Toole, K. McQuinn and R. Slaymaker (2022). Rental Inflation
and Stabilisation Policies: International Evidence and the Irish Experience. ESRI
Research Series Report No.136, Economic and Social Research Institute: Dublin.
https://doi.org/10.26504/rs136.
Corlett, A. and L. Judge (2017). Home Affront: Housing Across the Generations. Resolution
Foundation.
50 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
Corrigan, E. (2019). Attitudinal survey of mature homeowners preliminary analysis
mimeo.
Corrigan, E., D. Foley, K. McQuinn, C. OToole and R. Slaymaker (2019). Exploring
affordability in the Irish housing market, The Economic and Social Review,
50(1,Spring), 119-157.
Corrigan, E. and D. Watson (2019). Social housing in the Irish housing market, The
Economic and Social Review, 50 (1, Spring), pp. 213-248.
Crawford, R. and C. O’Dea (2012). The Adequacy of Wealth among those Approaching
Retirement. Institute for Fiscal Studies.
Crawford, R. and P. Simpson (2020). The impact of house prices on pension saving in
early adulthood’, IFS Working Paper 2020/38.
De Burca, O., R. Kelly and E. O’Brien (2021). A financial stability perspective on the First
Home shared equity scheme’, Financial Stability Notes 12/FS/21, Central Bank of
Ireland.
Delfani, N., J. De Deken and C. Dewilde (2014). Home-Ownership and Pensions: Negative
Correlation, but No Trade-off’, Housing Studies, 29(5), 657-676.
https://doi.org/10.1080/02673037.2014.882495.
Delfani, N., J. De Deken and C. Dewilde (2015). Poor because of low pensions or
expensive housing? The combined impact of pension and housing systems on
poverty among the elderly’, International Journal of Housing Policy, 15(3),
260-284. https://doi.org/10.1080/14616718.2015.1004880.
Department of Social Protection (2022). The Design Principles for Irelands Automatic
Enrolment Retirement Savings System. Government of Ireland.
Dewilde, C. and P. Raeymaeckers (2008). The trade-off between home-ownership and
pensions: Individual and institutional determinants of old-age poverty’, Ageing
and Society, 28(6), 805-830. Cambridge Core.
https://doi.org/10.1017/S0144686X08007277.
Doolan, M., B. Roantree and R. Slaymaker (2022). Low Income Renters and Housing
Supports, ESRI Research Series Report No. 141. Economic and Social Research
Institute: Dublin. https://doi.org/10.26504/rs141.
European Commission (2021). The 2021 Pension Adequacy Report: Current and Future
Income Adequacy in Old Age in the EU. European Commission.
Fahey, T. (2003). Is there a Trade-Off between Pensions and Home Ownership? An
exploration of the Irish case’, Journal of European Social Policy, 13(2), 159-173.
https://doi.org/10.1177/0958928703013002004.
Fahey, T., B. Nolan and B. Maître (2004a). Housing Expenditures and Income Poverty in
EU Countries’, Journal of Social Policy, 33(3), 437-454. Cambridge Core.
https://doi.org/10.1017/S0047279404007767.
Fahey, T., B. Nolan and B. Maître (2004b). Housing, Poverty and Wealth in Ireland.
Institute of Public Administration and Combat Poverty Agency.
Fahey, T. and M. Norris (2010). Housing’, in The Oxford Handbook of the Welfare State.
Oxford University Press.
Favara, G. and J. Imbs (2015). Credit supply and the price of housing’, American Economic
Review, 105(3), pp. 958-92.
References | 51
Gaffney, E. (2018). ‘Residential property price segments and mortgage finance, Financial
Stability Notes 11/FS/18, Central Bank of Ireland.
Gaffney, E. and C. Kinghan (2021). ‘Mortgage lending in Ireland during the 2010s,
Financial Stability Notes 09/FS/21, Central Bank of Ireland.
Government of Ireland (2010). National Pensions Framework. Stationery Office.
Government of Ireland (2018). A Roadmap for Pensions Reform 2018-2023. Stationery
Office.
Government of Ireland (2021). Report of the Commission on Pensions. Government of
Ireland. https://www.gov.ie/en/publication/6cb6d-report-of-the-commission-
on-pensions/.
Grace, T., N. Hallissey and M. Woods (2015). ‘The Instruments of Macro-Prudential
Policy, Quarterly Bulletin Articles, issue 01, pp. 90-105. Central Bank of Ireland.
Irish Fiscal Advisory Council (2020). Long Term Sustainability Report: Fiscal Challenges and
Risks 2025-2050.
Kelly, C. and F. McCann (2016). Rental markets, savings and the accumulation of
mortgage deposits, Quarterly Bulletin Articles, issue 04, pp. 56-70. Central Bank
of Ireland.
Kelly, R. and E. Mazza (2019). A measure of bindingness in the Irish mortgage market,
Financial Stability Notes 12/FS/19, Central Bank of Ireland.
https://EconPapers.repec.org/RePEc:cbi:fsnote:12/fs/19.
Kelly, R., F. McCann and C. O’Toole (2018). Credit conditions, macroprudential policy and
house prices, Journal of Housing Economics, 41, 153-167.
Kinghan, C. (2018). Macroprudential measures and Irish mortgage lending: Insights from
H1 2018, Financial Stability Notes, 08/FS/18, Central Bank of Ireland.
Knoff, M., J. Been, R. Alessie, K. Caminada, K. Goudswaard and A. Kalwu (2016).
Measuring retirement savings adequacy: Developing a multi-pillar approach in
the Netherlands’, Journal of Pension Economics and Finance, 15(1), 55-89.
Cambridge Core. https://doi.org/10.1017/S1474747214000341.
Lawless, M. and D. Lynch (2017). Gifts and inheritances in Ireland. Working Paper No.
579. Economic and Social Research Institute: Dublin.
Lersch, P.M. and C. Dewilde (2015). Employment insecurity and first-time
homeownership: Evidence from twenty-two European countries. Environment
and Planning A, 47(3), pp.607-624.
Lozano Alcántara, A. and C. Vogel (2021). Rising housing costs and income poverty
among the elderly in Germany’, Housing Studies, 1-19.
https://doi.org/10.1080/02673037.2021.1935759.
McQuinn, K. (2021). 'House prices and mortgage credit: Empirical evidence for Ireland
An update', ESRI Quarterly Economic Commentary Research Note No. 20210101.
Economic and Social Research Institute: Dublin.
https://doi.org/10.26504/rn20210101.
McQuinn, K., C. O’Toole and R. Slaymaker (2021). Credit access, macroprudential rules
and policy interventions: Lessons for potential first-time buyers’, Journal of Policy
Modeling, 43(5), 944-963. https://doi.org/10.1016/j.jpolmod.2021.03.013.
52 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
Mulligan, E., D. Wijeratne and M. Maher (2019). Pensions in Ireland: The Perspectives of
Irish Citizens. Whitaker Institute.
Nivakoski, S. (2014). Determinants of Pension Coverage and Retirement Income
Replacement Rates Evidence from TILDA’, The Economic and Social Review,
45(3), 299-328.
Nivakoski, S. and A. Barrett (2019). Estimating, and Interpreting, Retirement Income
Replacement Rates’, The Economic and Social Review, 50(3), 587-609.
Nolan, A., A. Whelan, S. McGuinness and B. Maître (2019). Gender, Pensions and Income
in Retirement. ESRI Research Series Report No. 87. Economic and Social Research
Institute: Dublin. https://doi.org/10.26504/rs87.
Norris, M. (2016). Property, family and the Irish welfare state. Palgrave Macmillan, Cham,
Switzerland.
OECD (2014). OECD Reviews of Pensions Systems: Ireland. OECD.
OECD (2021). Pensions at a Glance 2021 OECD and G20 Indicators. OECD.
https://www.oecd-ilibrary.org/docserver/ca401ebd-
en.pdf?expires=1646922288&id=id&accname=guest&checksum=E84FC4F0BDA
40C00D8F0D2EE7E597438.
O’Toole, C. and R. Slaymaker (2020). A Review of the Rebuilding Ireland Home Loan, ESRI
Research Series Report No. 104. Economic and Social Research Institute: Dublin.
https://doi.org/10.26504/rs104.
O’Toole, C., R. Slaymaker, K. McQuinn, C. Coffey and E. Corrigan (2020). Exploring the
short-run implications of the COVID-19 pandemic on affordability in the Irish
private rental market, ESRI Research Series Report No. 108. Economic and Social
Research Institute: Dublin. https://doi.org/10.26504/rs108.
Roantree, B., B. Maître, A. McTague and I. Privalko (2021). Poverty, income inequality and
living standards in Ireland. Economic and Social Research Institute and The
Community Foundation for Ireland: Dublin.
https://doi.org/10.26504/bkmnext412.
Stebbing, A. and B. Spies-Butcher (2016). The decline of a homeowning society? Asset-
based welfare, retirement and intergenerational equity in Australia’, Housing
Studies, 31(2), pp.190-207.
Whelan, B.J. and G.M. Savva (2013). Design and Methodology of The Irish Longitudinal
Study on Ageing, J. Am. Geriatr. Soc., 61, S265-S268.
https://doi.org/10.1111/jgs.12199.
Yates, J. and B. Bradbury (2010). Home ownership as a (crumbling) fourth pillar of social
insurance in Australia’, Journal of Housing and the Built Environment, 25(2),
193-211. JSTOR.
Yates, J., H. Kendig, B. Phillips, V. Mulligan and R. Tanton (2008). Sustaining fair shares:
The Australian housing system and intergenerational sustainability (AHURI Final
Report No. 111). Australian Housing and Urban Research Institute.
https://www.ahuri.edu.au/sites/default/files/migration/documents/AHURI_Fin
al_Report_No111_Sustaining_fair_shares_the_Australian_housing_system_and
_intergenerational_sustainability.pdf.
Appendix I | 53
APPENDIX I SUPPLEMENTARY RESEARCH FOR CHAPTER 3
TABLE A.1 EVIDENCE OF LIKELIHOOD OF RECEIVING GIFT / AMOUNT BY RECIPIENT
CHARACTERISTICS
Overall Age 16-24 Age 25-49 Age 50+ Homeowner
Non-
Homeowner
Gift (%)
No gift >€5,000
73.3
81.3
70.9
86.6
71.8
75.0
Gift >€5,000
26.7
18.7
29.1
13.4
28.2
25.0
Value of Gift (€)
Mean
38,681
16,368
40,187
35,954
41,128
34,381
Median 10,000 6,667 10,000 10,000 10,000 10,000
Source: Authorscalculations from TILDA.
Note: Gift amounts conditional on having received a gift. Assumes that all non-resident children of the TILDA participant(s) receive an equal
amount.
TABLE A.2 25TH PERCENTILE HOUSE PRICE BY NUTS 3 REGION 2019
NUTS 3 region
25th percentile house price 2019 (€)
Border
80,000
Midlands
111,000
West
105,000
Dublin
278,000
Mid-East
210,000
Mid-West
113,000
South-East
127,500
South-West
160,000
Source: Authorscalculations from Residential Property Price Register.
Appendix II | 55
APPENDIX II SUPPLEMENTARY RESEARCH FOR CHAPTER 4
TABLE A.3 LOGISTIC REGRESSION OF THE FACTORS ASSOCIATED WITH AROP, BASELINE
SIMULATIONS, NARROW INCOME MEASURE
(1)
(2)
(3)
BHC
AHC
Share with income in retirement that is:
<60% median <50% median <60% median <50% median
Living in
Dublin (reference)
Urban area outside Dublin
1.091
0.833
0.883
0.608**
Rural area
1.480**
1.214
0.938
0.671**
Household type
Non-farming household (reference)
Farming household
1.365
0.941
1.065
1.228
Cohabitation status in working life
Married/cohabitating (reference)
Single
1.387
**
0.755
4.824***
3.681***
Gender
Man (reference)
Woman
1.252
*
1.331 1.514*** 1.265*
Education
Primary or lower (reference)
Lower secondary
1.146
1.324
0.622**
1.017
Upper secondary
0.928
1.071
0.396***
0.845
Post-secondary < degree
0.736
0.804
0.318***
0.635*
Post-secondary degree or higher
0.686
0.982
0.170***
0.518**
Observations
1,904 1,904 1,904 1,904
Source: Authorscalculations using data from the Irish Longitudinal Study of Ageing (TILDA).
Note: Coefficients show odds ratios from logistic regressions. Stars show statistical significance, indicating a p value of < 0.05
(*),< 0.01(**) and < 0.001 (***) respectively.
56 | Future trends in housing tenure and the adequacy of retirement income
FIGURE A.1 DISTRIBUTION OF AFTER HOUSING COSTS INCOME, BY SCENARIO (BROAD
DEFINITION)
Source: Authorscalculations using data from The Irish Longitudinal Study of Ageing (TILDA).
Notes: After housing costs disposable income constructed as described in Chapter 4, equivalised using the modified OECD equivalence
scale. Estimate from kernel density plot with data censored at €50,000 per year for legibility.
FIGURE A.2 DISTRIBUTION OF AFTER HOUSING COSTS INCOME, BY SCENARIO (NARROW
DEFINITION)
Source: Authorscalculations using data from The Irish Longitudinal Study of Ageing (TILDA).
Notes: After housing costs disposable income constructed as described in Chapter 4, equivalised using the modified OECD equivalence
scale. Estimate from kernel density plot with data censored at €50,000 per year for legibility.
0
0.00001
0.00002
0.00003
0.00004
0.00005
0.00006
0.00007
0.00008
0.00009
€0 €10,000 €20,000 €30,000 €40,000 €50,000
Density
Annual equivalised after housing costs disposable income
Baseline High Medium Low
0
0.00002
0.00004
0.00006
0.00008
0.0001
0.00012
0.00014
0.00016
0.00018
0.0002
€0 €10,000 €20,000 €30,000 €40,000 €50,000
Density
Annual equivalised after housing costs disposable income
Baseline High Medium Low
Whitaker Patrons and Corporate Members
The ESRI plays a leading role in producing independent research which allows policymakers in
Ireland to better understand the economic and social landscape which shapes Ireland. One goal
of the ESRI is to ensure that the Institute has a strong revenue stream to fund valuable,
independent social and economic research initiatives that will have a long-term impact on Irish
society. In 2021, we launched a compelling new membership programme with two categories
of membership:
1) Whitaker Patron and
2) Corporate Membership
We would like to acknowledge the following organisations and thank them for their valuable
support:
WHITAKER PATRONS
EirGrid
ICON
Davy
ESB
Intel
Microsoft
Kingspan
Meta
CORPORATE MEMBERSHIP
Musgrave Group
OHM Group (Jaguar)
Tesco
Enterprise Ireland
Matheson
PwC
ABP Food Group
KPMG
Ibec
DCC
Department of Transport
FBD Insurance
Department of Further and Higher Education, Research, Innovation and Science
IDA Ireland
Irish Water
Greencoat Capital
Malin
Fáilte Ireland
SIPTU
Bord Gáis Energy
Department of Agriculture, Food and the Marine
Irish Farmers' Association
Irish Life
National Treasury Management Agency
Department of Foreign Affairs
Whitaker Square,
Sir John Rogerson’s Quay,
Dublin 2
Telephone +353 1 863 2000
Web www.esri.ie
Twitter @ESRIDublin