Journal of Economic Perspectives—Volume 25, Number 1—Winter 2011—Pages 3–28
M
M
any observers have argued that the regulatory framework in place
any observers have argued that the regulatory framework in place
prior to the global nancial crisis was de cient because it was largely
prior to the global  nancial crisis was de cient because it was largely
“microprudential” in nature (Crockett, 2000; Borio, Fur ne, and Lowe,
“microprudential” in nature (Crockett, 2000; Borio, Fur ne, and Lowe,
2001; Borio, 2003; Kashyap and Stein, 2004; Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein, 2008;
2001; Borio, 2003; Kashyap and Stein, 2004; Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein, 2008;
Brunnermeier, Crockett, Goodhart, Persaud, and Shin, 2009; Bank of England,
Brunnermeier, Crockett, Goodhart, Persaud, and Shin, 2009; Bank of England,
2009; French et al., 2010). A microprudential approach is one in which regulation
2009; French et al., 2010). A microprudential approach is one in which regulation
is partial equilibrium in its conception and aimed at preventing the costly failure of
is partial equilibrium in its conception and aimed at preventing the costly failure of
individual  nancial institutions. By contrast, a “macroprudential” approach recog-
individual  nancial institutions. By contrast, a “macroprudential” approach recog-
nizes the importance of general equilibrium effects, and seeks to safeguard the
nizes the importance of general equilibrium effects, and seeks to safeguard the
nancial system as a whole. In the aftermath of the crisis, there seems to be agree-
nancial system as a whole. In the aftermath of the crisis, there seems to be agree-
ment among both academics and policymakers that nancial regulation needs to
ment among both academics and policymakers that  nancial regulation needs to
move in a macroprudential direction. For example, according to Federal Reserve
move in a macroprudential direction. For example, according to Federal Reserve
Chairman Ben Bernanke (2008):
Chairman Ben Bernanke (2008):
A Macroprudential Approach to
Financial Regulation
Samuel G. Hanson is a Ph.D. Candidate in Business Economics, Harvard University,
Samuel G. Hanson is a Ph.D. Candidate in Business Economics, Harvard University,
Cambridge, Massachusetts. From February to December 2009, Hanson was a Special Assistant
Cambridge, Massachusetts. From February to December 2009, Hanson was a Special Assistant
at the U.S. Department of the Treasury, Washington, D.C. Anil K Kashyap is Edward Eagle
at the U.S. Department of the Treasury, Washington, D.C. Anil K Kashyap is Edward Eagle
Brown Professor of Economics and Finance and Richard N. Rosett Faculty Fellow, University of
Brown Professor of Economics and Finance and Richard N. Rosett Faculty Fellow, University of
Chicago Booth School of Business, Chicago, Illinois. Jeremy C. Stein is Moise Y. Safra Professor
Chicago Booth School of Business, Chicago, Illinois. Jeremy C. Stein is Moise Y. Safra Professor
of Economics, Harvard University, Cambridge, Massachusetts. From February to July 2009,
of Economics, Harvard University, Cambridge, Massachusetts. From February to July 2009,
Stein was Senior Advisor to the Secretary, U.S. Department of the Treasury, and Staff Member
Stein was Senior Advisor to the Secretary, U.S. Department of the Treasury, and Staff Member
of the National Economic Council, both in Washington, D.C. Kashyap and Stein are both
of the National Economic Council, both in Washington, D.C. Kashyap and Stein are both
Research Associates, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Research Associates, National Bureau of Economic Research, Cambridge, Massachusetts.
Their e-mail addresses are
Their e-mail addresses are
,
,
,
,
and
and
.
.
doi=10.1257/jep.25.1.3
Samuel G. Hanson, Anil K Kashyap, and
Jeremy C. Stein
4 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Going forward, a critical question for regulators and supervisors is what their
appropriate “ eld of vision” should be. Under our current system of safety-
and-soundness regulation, supervisors often focus on the  nancial conditions
of individual institutions in isolation. An alternative approach, which has been
called systemwide or macroprudential oversight, would broaden the mandate
of regulators and supervisors to encompass consideration of potential systemic
risks and weaknesses as well.
In this paper, we offer a detailed vision for how a macroprudential regime
In this paper, we offer a detailed vision for how a macroprudential regime
might be designed. Our prescriptions follow from a speci c theory of how modern
might be designed. Our prescriptions follow from a speci c theory of how modern
nancial crises unfold and why both an unregulated nancial system, as well as one
nancial crises unfold and why both an unregulated  nancial system, as well as one
based on capital rules that only apply to traditional banks, is likely to be fragile. We
based on capital rules that only apply to traditional banks, is likely to be fragile. We
begin by identifying the key market failures at work: why individual nancial  rms,
begin by identifying the key market failures at work: why individual  nancial  rms,
acting in their own interests, deviate from what a social planner would have them
acting in their own interests, deviate from what a social planner would have them
do. Next, we discuss a number of concrete steps to remedy these market failures. We
do. Next, we discuss a number of concrete steps to remedy these market failures. We
conclude the paper by comparing our proposals to recent regulatory reforms in the
conclude the paper by comparing our proposals to recent regulatory reforms in the
United States and to proposed global banking reforms.
United States and to proposed global banking reforms.
Theories of Financial Regulation
Theories of Financial Regulation
Microprudential Regulation
Microprudential Regulation
Traditional microprudential regulation of banks is based on the following
Traditional microprudential regulation of banks is based on the following
logic. Banks nance themselves with government-insured deposits. While deposit
logic. Banks  nance themselves with government-insured deposits. While deposit
insurance has the valuable effect of preventing runs (Diamond and Dybvig, 1983;
insurance has the valuable effect of preventing runs (Diamond and Dybvig, 1983;
Bryant, 1980), it creates an incentive for bank managers to take excessive risks,
Bryant, 1980), it creates an incentive for bank managers to take excessive risks,
knowing that losses will be covered by the taxpayer. The goal of capital regulation
knowing that losses will be covered by the taxpayer. The goal of capital regulation
is to force banks to internalize losses, thereby protecting the deposit insurance
is to force banks to internalize losses, thereby protecting the deposit insurance
fund and mitigating moral hazard. Thus, if the probability of the deposit insurer
fund and mitigating moral hazard. Thus, if the probability of the deposit insurer
bearing losses is reduced to a low enough level, microprudential regulation is
bearing losses is reduced to a low enough level, microprudential regulation is
doing its job.
doing its job.
To be speci c, consider a bank with assets of $100 that is  nanced with insured
To be speci c, consider a bank with assets of $100 that is  nanced with insured
deposits and some amount of capital. Suppose that the regulator can check on the
deposits and some amount of capital. Suppose that the regulator can check on the
bank once a quarter. Suppose further that the volatility of the bank’s assets is such
bank once a quarter. Suppose further that the volatility of the bank’s assets is such
that with probability 99.5 percent, the assets do not decline in value by more than
that with probability 99.5 percent, the assets do not decline in value by more than
6 percent during a quarter. Then if the goal of policy is to reduce the probability
6 percent during a quarter. Then if the goal of policy is to reduce the probability
of bank failure (whereby capital is wiped out and there are losses to the deposit
of bank failure (whereby capital is wiped out and there are losses to the deposit
insurance fund) to 0.5 percent, this goal can be accomplished by requiring the bank
insurance fund) to 0.5 percent, this goal can be accomplished by requiring the bank
to have capital equal to 6 percent of its assets as a cushion against losses. Notice
to have capital equal to 6 percent of its assets as a cushion against losses. Notice
that in this setting, the exact form of the capital cushion is not important. It can be
that in this setting, the exact form of the capital cushion is not important. It can be
common equity, but it can equally well be preferred stock, or subordinated debt, as
common equity, but it can equally well be preferred stock, or subordinated debt, as
long as these instruments are not explicitly or implicitly insured—that is, as long as
long as these instruments are not explicitly or implicitly insured—that is, as long as
they will in fact bear losses in a bad state.
they will in fact bear losses in a bad state.
Samuel G. Hanson, Anil K Kashyap, and Jeremy C. Stein 5
An important element of existing capital regulation is the presumption that
An important element of existing capital regulation is the presumption that
a bank will take immediate steps to restore its capital ratio in the wake of losses.
a bank will take immediate steps to restore its capital ratio in the wake of losses.
Returning to our example, suppose the bank starts out with capital of $6 but then
Returning to our example, suppose the bank starts out with capital of $6 but then
over the next quarter experiences losses of $2, so that its capital falls to $4. If the
over the next quarter experiences losses of $2, so that its capital falls to $4. If the
volatility of its assets remains unchanged, in order for its probability of failure over
volatility of its assets remains unchanged, in order for its probability of failure over
the subsequent quarter to stay at 0.5 percent, it would need to bring its capital ratio
the subsequent quarter to stay at 0.5 percent, it would need to bring its capital ratio
back up to 6 percent. It could do so in one of two ways: either by going to the market
back up to 6 percent. It could do so in one of two ways: either by going to the market
and raising $2 of fresh capital, or by leaving its capital unchanged and shrinking its
and raising $2 of fresh capital, or by leaving its capital unchanged and shrinking its
asset base to $66.67 (4/66.67
asset base to $66.67 (4/66.67
=
=
6 percent).
6 percent).
The basic critique of microprudential regulation can be understood as follows.
The basic critique of microprudential regulation can be understood as follows.
When a microprudentially oriented regulator pushes a troubled bank to restore
When a microprudentially oriented regulator pushes a troubled bank to restore
its capital ratio,
its capital ratio, the regulator does not care whether the bank adjusts via the numerator or
via the denominator—that is, by raising new capital or by shrinking assets
. Either way, the
. Either way, the
bank’s probability of failure is brought back to a tolerable level, which is all that a
bank’s probability of failure is brought back to a tolerable level, which is all that a
microprudential regulator cares about.
microprudential regulator cares about.
Such indifference to the method of adjustment makes sense if we are consid-
Such indifference to the method of adjustment makes sense if we are consid-
ering a single bank that is in trouble for idiosyncratic reasons. If that bank chooses
ering a single bank that is in trouble for idiosyncratic reasons. If that bank chooses
to shrink its assets—perhaps by cutting back on lending—others can pick up the
to shrink its assets—perhaps by cutting back on lending—others can pick up the
slack. Indeed, asset shrinkage in this case can be part of a healthy Darwinian process,
slack. Indeed, asset shrinkage in this case can be part of a healthy Darwinian process,
whereby market share is transferred from weaker troubled institutions to their
whereby market share is transferred from weaker troubled institutions to their
stronger peers. However, if a large fraction of the  nancial system is in dif culty, a
stronger peers. However, if a large fraction of the  nancial system is in dif culty, a
simultaneous attempt by many institutions to shrink their assets is likely to be more
simultaneous attempt by many institutions to shrink their assets is likely to be more
damaging to the economy.
damaging to the economy.
Macroprudential Regulation
Macroprudential Regulation
In the simplest terms, one can characterize the macroprudential approach to
In the simplest terms, one can characterize the macroprudential approach to
nancial regulation as
nancial regulation as an effort to control the social costs associated with excessive balance-
sheet shrinkage on the part of multiple  nancial institutions hit with a common shock
. To
. To
make a compelling case for macroprudential regulation, two questions must be
make a compelling case for macroprudential regulation, two questions must be
answered. First, what are the costs imposed on society when many nancial rms
answered. First, what are the costs imposed on society when many  nancial rms
shrink their assets at the same time? Second, why do individual  rms not internalize
shrink their assets at the same time? Second, why do individual  rms not internalize
these costs? That is, why do they not raise fresh capital rather than reduce assets
these costs? That is, why do they not raise fresh capital rather than reduce assets
when a bad shock hits? Or alternatively, why do they not build suf ciently large
when a bad shock hits? Or alternatively, why do they not build suf ciently large
capital buffers ahead of time so that they can withstand a shock without needing
capital buffers ahead of time so that they can withstand a shock without needing
either to raise capital or to reduce assets?
either to raise capital or to reduce assets?
Generalized asset shrinkage has two primary costs: credit-crunch and re-sale
Generalized asset shrinkage has two primary costs: credit-crunch and  re-sale
effects. If banks shrink their assets by cutting new lending, operating rms nd
effects. If banks shrink their assets by cutting new lending, operating  rms nd
credit more expensive and reduce investment and employment, with contractionary
credit more expensive and reduce investment and employment, with contractionary
consequences for the economy. If a large number of banks instead shrink their
consequences for the economy. If a large number of banks instead shrink their
assets by all dumping the same illiquid securities (think of toxic mortgage-backed
assets by all dumping the same illiquid securities (think of toxic mortgage-backed
securities) the prices of these securities can drop sharply in a “ re sale” of the sort
securities) the prices of these securities can drop sharply in a “ re sale” of the sort
described by Shleifer and Vishny in this issue. Moreover, the re-sale and credit-
described by Shleifer and Vishny in this issue. Moreover, the  re-sale and credit-
crunch effects are intimately connected (Diamond and Rajan, 2009; Shleifer and
crunch effects are intimately connected (Diamond and Rajan, 2009; Shleifer and
6 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Vishny, 2010; Stein, 2010a). If a toxic mortgage security falls in price to the point
Vishny, 2010; Stein, 2010a). If a toxic mortgage security falls in price to the point
where it offers a (risk-adjusted) 20 percent rate of return to a prospective buyer, this
where it offers a (risk-adjusted) 20 percent rate of return to a prospective buyer, this
will tend to drive the rate on new loans up towards 20 percent as well—since from
will tend to drive the rate on new loans up towards 20 percent as well—since from
the perspective of an intermediary that can choose to either make new loans or buy
the perspective of an intermediary that can choose to either make new loans or buy
distressed securities, the expected rate of return on the two must be equalized. In
distressed securities, the expected rate of return on the two must be equalized. In
other words, in market equilibrium, the real costs of re sales manifest themselves
other words, in market equilibrium, the real costs of  re sales manifest themselves
in the further deepening of credit crunches. Ivashina and Scharfstein (2010) offer
in the further deepening of credit crunches. Ivashina and Scharfstein (2010) offer
evidence on the extent of credit contraction during the recent crisis.
evidence on the extent of credit contraction during the recent crisis.
Of course, to make a case for regulatory intervention, one has to explain why
Of course, to make a case for regulatory intervention, one has to explain why
these 20 percent rates of return inside the nancial sector—which are much higher
these 20 percent rates of return inside the  nancial sector—which are much higher
than the outside rates on, say, Treasury securities—don’t naturally draw in enough
than the outside rates on, say, Treasury securities—don’t naturally draw in enough
private capital to eliminate the return differentials. One reason why capital is immo-
private capital to eliminate the return differentials. One reason why capital is immo-
bile once a crisis is underway is the “debt overhang” problem identi ed by Myers
bile once a crisis is underway is the “debt overhang” problem identi ed by Myers
(1977). Once a bank is in serious trouble and its debt is impaired in value, the
(1977). Once a bank is in serious trouble and its debt is impaired in value, the
bank is reluctant to raise new equity even to fund investments that have a positive
bank is reluctant to raise new equity even to fund investments that have a positive
net present value. This is because much of the value that is created is siphoned off
net present value. This is because much of the value that is created is siphoned off
by the more senior creditors. Given the debt overhang problem, banks that act in
by the more senior creditors. Given the debt overhang problem, banks that act in
the interests of their shareholders will tend to x their damaged capital ratios by
the interests of their shareholders will tend to  x their damaged capital ratios by
shrinking assets rather than by raising new capital, even when the latter is more
shrinking assets rather than by raising new capital, even when the latter is more
desirable from a social perspective.
desirable from a social perspective.
If so, why don’t banks voluntarily build up adequate buffer stocks of excess
If so, why don’t banks voluntarily build up adequate buffer stocks of excess
capital in good times, when debt overhang is not yet a concern, so they can absorb
capital in good times, when debt overhang is not yet a concern, so they can absorb
losses in bad times without having to either shrink assets or raise new capital under
losses in bad times without having to either shrink assets or raise new capital under
duress? After all, such a dry-powder strategy would allow them to exploit pro table
duress? After all, such a dry-powder strategy would allow them to exploit pro table
opportunities should a crisis arise. This question is addressed in Stein (2010a), who
opportunities should a crisis arise. This question is addressed in Stein (2010a), who
extends the re-sale model to consider banks’ initial choices of capital structure.
extends the  re-sale model to consider banks’ initial choices of capital structure.
He shows that if short-term debt is a cheaper form of nance than equity, banks
He shows that if short-term debt is a cheaper form of  nance than equity, banks
will tend to take on socially excessive levels of debt: while the banks capture the
will tend to take on socially excessive levels of debt: while the banks capture the
bene ts of cheap debt  nance, they do not internalize all of its costs.
bene ts of cheap debt  nance, they do not internalize all of its costs.
1
1
In particular,
In particular,
when Bank A takes on more debt, it does not account for the fact that by doing
when Bank A takes on more debt, it does not account for the fact that by doing
so, it degrades the collateral value of any assets it holds in common with another
so, it degrades the collateral value of any assets it holds in common with another
Bank B—since in a crisis state of the world, A’s re-selling of its assets lowers the
Bank B—since in a crisis state of the world, As  re-selling of its assets lowers the
liquidation value that B can realize for these same assets.
liquidation value that B can realize for these same assets.
2
2
1
The assumption that short-term debt is a cheap form of  nance represents a particular deviation from
the Modigliani–Miller (1958) capital-structure irrelevance framework. In the context of  nancial  rms,
this deviation can arise to the extent that their short-term claims are “money-like” and carry a premium
that re ects their usefulness as a transactions medium. We discuss this point in greater detail below.
2
A subtlety is that this is a pecuniary externality—that is, it works through prices. For a pecuniary
externality to cause a misallocation of resources, one requires a departure from the standard assump-
tions that deliver the fundamental welfare theorems (Geanakoplos and Polemarchakis, 1986). In Stein
(2010a), this departure is in the form of a collateral constraint: banks’ ability to raise short-term debt is
constrained by the collateral value of their assets.
A Macroprudential Approach to Financial Regulation 7
In sum, a model based on  re sales and credit crunches suggests that  nancial
In sum, a model based on  re sales and credit crunches suggests that  nancial
institutions have overly strong incentives 1) to shrink assets rather than recapitalize
institutions have overly strong incentives 1) to shrink assets rather than recapitalize
once a crisis is underway, and 2) to operate with too thin capital buffers before a
once a crisis is underway, and 2) to operate with too thin capital buffers before a
crisis occurs, thereby raising the probability of an eventual crisis and systemwide
crisis occurs, thereby raising the probability of an eventual crisis and systemwide
balance-sheet contraction. Therefore, the macroprudential approach to capital
balance-sheet contraction. Therefore, the macroprudential approach to capital
regulation aims to counterbalance these two tendencies. With this in mind, we turn
regulation aims to counterbalance these two tendencies. With this in mind, we turn
next to some of the individual items in the macroprudential toolkit.
next to some of the individual items in the macroprudential toolkit.
Before doing so, however, we should emphasize that, in contrast to the tradi-
Before doing so, however, we should emphasize that, in contrast to the tradi-
tional view,
tional view, nothing in this alternative theory relies on the existence of deposit insurance
.
.
In other words, in a model of crises based on re sales, there is socially excessive
In other words, in a model of crises based on  re sales, there is socially excessive
balance-sheet shrinkage, and a rationale for regulation, even absent government
balance-sheet shrinkage, and a rationale for regulation, even absent government
deposit insurance. Thus, there is a strong presumption that macroprudential regu-
deposit insurance. Thus, there is a strong presumption that macroprudential regu-
lation should apply to more than just insured deposit-takers. The broader point
lation should apply to more than just insured deposit-takers. The broader point
(stressed by Tucker, 2010, and Kashyap, Berner, and Goodhart, forthcoming) is
(stressed by Tucker, 2010, and Kashyap, Berner, and Goodhart, forthcoming) is
that regulators need to pay attention to all the channels through which the actions
that regulators need to pay attention to all the channels through which the actions
of nancial institutions—both those who are insured and those who are not—can
of  nancial institutions—both those who are insured and those who are not—can
cause damage.
cause damage.
Macroprudential Tools
Macroprudential Tools
We now discuss six sets of tools that can be helpful in implementing a macro-
We now discuss six sets of tools that can be helpful in implementing a macro-
prudential approach to nancial regulation. Our goal here is not to provide a
prudential approach to  nancial regulation. Our goal here is not to provide a
comprehensive laundry list of reform proposals, but rather to show how a particular
comprehensive laundry list of reform proposals, but rather to show how a particular
conceptual framework provides a uni ed way of thinking about what otherwise
conceptual framework provides a uni ed way of thinking about what otherwise
might seem like a hodgepodge of different  xes.
might seem like a hodgepodge of different  xes.
As a prelude, note that if the goal of regulation is to prevent nancial rms
As a prelude, note that if the goal of regulation is to prevent  nancial rms
from shrinking their balance sheets excessively in an adverse state of the world, a
from shrinking their balance sheets excessively in an adverse state of the world, a
simple accounting identity imposes a lot of discipline on our thinking. In particular,
simple accounting identity imposes a lot of discipline on our thinking. In particular,
when a bank is hit with a shock that depletes its capital, there are only two ways to
when a bank is hit with a shock that depletes its capital, there are only two ways to
prevent it from shrinking its assets: 1) it can raise new capital to replace that which
prevent it from shrinking its assets: 1) it can raise new capital to replace that which
was lost; or 2) it can let its ratio of capital to assets decline. Many of the tools that we
was lost; or 2) it can let its ratio of capital to assets decline. Many of the tools that we
discuss are just different mechanisms for facilitating adjustment on one of these two
discuss are just different mechanisms for facilitating adjustment on one of these two
margins. We start with capital proposals and then broaden the discussion to other
margins. We start with capital proposals and then broaden the discussion to other
options that have heretofore been outside of the regulatory toolkit.
options that have heretofore been outside of the regulatory toolkit.
Time-Varying Capital Requirements
Time-Varying Capital Requirements
One intuitively appealing response to the problem of balance-sheet shrinkage
One intuitively appealing response to the problem of balance-sheet shrinkage
is to move to a regime of time-varying capital requirements, with banks being asked
is to move to a regime of time-varying capital requirements, with banks being asked
to maintain higher ratios of capital to assets in good times than in bad times. Under
to maintain higher ratios of capital to assets in good times than in bad times. Under
such a rule, banks can draw down their buffers when an adverse shock hits and
such a rule, banks can draw down their buffers when an adverse shock hits and
continue operating with less pressure to shrink assets. Kashyap and Stein (2004)
continue operating with less pressure to shrink assets. Kashyap and Stein (2004)
argue that time-varying capital requirements emerge as an optimal scheme in a
argue that time-varying capital requirements emerge as an optimal scheme in a
8 Journal of Economic Perspectives
model where the social planner maximizes a welfare function that weights both
model where the social planner maximizes a welfare function that weights both
1) the microprudential objective of protecting the deposit insurance fund and
1) the microprudential objective of protecting the deposit insurance fund and
2) the macroprudential objective of maintaining credit creation during recessions.
2) the macroprudential objective of maintaining credit creation during recessions.
A planner concerned with both objectives should be willing to tolerate a higher
A planner concerned with both objectives should be willing to tolerate a higher
probability of bank failure in bad times, when bank capital is scarce and credit
probability of bank failure in bad times, when bank capital is scarce and credit
supply is tight, than in good times.
supply is tight, than in good times.
One challenge in designing such a regime is that, in bad times, the regu-
One challenge in designing such a regime is that, in bad times, the regu-
latory capital requirement is often not the binding constraint on banks. Rather,
latory capital requirement is often not the binding constraint on banks. Rather,
as the risk of their assets rises, the market may impose a tougher test on banks
as the risk of their assets rises, the market may impose a tougher test on banks
than do regulators, refusing to fund institutions that are not strongly capitalized.
than do regulators, refusing to fund institutions that are not strongly capitalized.
3
3
Table 1 shows that, as of the rst quarter of 2010, the four largest U.S. banks had
Table 1 shows that, as of the  rst quarter of 2010, the four largest U.S. banks had
an average ratio of Tier 1 common equity to risk-weighted assets of 8.2 percent and
an average ratio of Tier 1 common equity to risk-weighted assets of 8.2 percent and
an average ratio of total Tier 1 capital (including preferred stock, for example)
an average ratio of total Tier 1 capital (including preferred stock, for example)
to risk-weighted assets of 10.7 percent. These are both well above the pre-crisis
to risk-weighted assets of 10.7 percent. These are both well above the pre-crisis
regulatory standard, which required a ratio of total Tier 1 capital to risk-weighted
regulatory standard, which required a ratio of total Tier 1 capital to risk-weighted
assets of 6 percent for a bank to be deemed “well capitalized.” Thus, even as the
assets of 6 percent for a bank to be deemed “well capitalized.” Thus, even as the
U.S. economy was emerging from a deep nancial crisis in early 2010, the regula-
U.S. economy was emerging from a deep  nancial crisis in early 2010, the regula-
tory constraint was nonbinding.
tory constraint was nonbinding.
This pattern implies that to achieve meaningful time variation in capital ratios,
This pattern implies that to achieve meaningful time variation in capital ratios,
the regulatory minimum in good times must substantially exceed the market-imposed standard
in bad times
. Thus, if the market standard for equity-to-assets in bad times is 8 percent,
. Thus, if the market standard for equity-to-assets in bad times is 8 percent,
and we want banks to be able to absorb losses of, say, 4 percent of assets without
and we want banks to be able to absorb losses of, say, 4 percent of assets without
pressure to shrink, then the regulatory minimum for equity-to-assets in good times
pressure to shrink, then the regulatory minimum for equity-to-assets in good times
3
This tendency may be ampli ed by the widespread use of “Value at Risk” (VaR) models by banks. As
measured volatility and hence VaR go up in bad times, such models mechanically call for banks to hold
higher ratios of capital. Thus, banks’ own internal risk management practices might compel shrinkage
even if market funding remains available.
Table 1
Capital Ratios for Top Four U.S. Banks, 2010Q1
Bank of
America Citigroup
JPMorgan
Chase
Wells
Fargo
Weighted
average
Total risk-weighted assets
($ millions)
1,519 1,023 1, 147 988
Tier 1 common equity to
risk-weighted assets (%)
7.6 9.1 9.1 7.1 8.2
Tier 1 capital to risk-weighted
assets (%)
10.2 11.2 11.5 10.0 10.7
Sources: Data is from the websites of individual banks.
Note: This table lists the capital ratios for the four largest U.S. banks as of 2010Q1.
Samuel G. Hanson, Anil K Kashyap, and Jeremy C. Stein 9
would have to be at least 12 percent. A loss on the order of 4 percent of assets is
would have to be at least 12 percent. A loss on the order of 4 percent of assets is
actually less severe than the experience of the major banks during the recent crisis;
actually less severe than the experience of the major banks during the recent crisis;
the IMF (2010) estimates that cumulative credit losses at U.S. banks from 2007 to
the IMF (2010) estimates that cumulative credit losses at U.S. banks from 2007 to
2010 were on the order of 7 percent of assets. Using this gure, one could argue for
2010 were on the order of 7 percent of assets. Using this  gure, one could argue for
a good-times regulatory minimum ratio of equity to assets of 15 percent. Either way,
a good-times regulatory minimum ratio of equity to assets of 15 percent. Either way,
these are high values, signi cantly higher than obtained from a microprudential
these are high values, signi cantly higher than obtained from a microprudential
calculation that asks only how much capital is needed to avert outright failure. (We
calculation that asks only how much capital is needed to avert outright failure. (We
examine the potential costs of raising capital requirements by this much below, in
examine the potential costs of raising capital requirements by this much below, in
the penultimate section of the paper.)
the penultimate section of the paper.)
Higher-Quality Capital
Higher-Quality Capital
Traditionally, the capital metric given the most attention by regulators has
Traditionally, the capital metric given the most attention by regulators has
been the ratio of total Tier 1 capital to risk-weighted assets. In addition to common
been the ratio of total Tier 1 capital to risk-weighted assets. In addition to common
equity, total Tier 1 capital includes, among other items, preferred stock. Thus, both
equity, total Tier 1 capital includes, among other items, preferred stock. Thus, both
equity and preferred have “counted in the same way towards satisfying capital
equity and preferred have “counted” in the same way towards satisfying capital
requirements. From a microprudential perspective, this makes perfect sense. If the
requirements. From a microprudential perspective, this makes perfect sense. If the
only concern is avoiding losses to the deposit insurer in the event of bank failure,
only concern is avoiding losses to the deposit insurer in the event of bank failure,
so long as both common and preferred holders are strictly junior in priority to the
so long as both common and preferred holders are strictly junior in priority to the
deposit insurer, they will provide the desired loss-absorption cushion.
deposit insurer, they will provide the desired loss-absorption cushion.
However, in the wake of the nancial crisis, many investors and regulators
However, in the wake of the  nancial crisis, many investors and regulators
have discussed the “quality” of a bank’s capital base and how common stock is a
have discussed the “quality” of a bank’s capital base and how common stock is a
“higher-quality” form of capital than preferred. While this distinction is hard to
“higher-quality” form of capital than preferred. While this distinction is hard to
understand from a microprudential loss-absorption perspective, it ows naturally
understand from a microprudential loss-absorption perspective, it  ows naturally
from the macroprudential approach, which focuses less on a static failure scenario
from the macroprudential approach, which focuses less on a static failure scenario
and more on enabling troubled institutions to recapitalize dynamically and remain
and more on enabling troubled institutions to recapitalize dynamically and remain
viable as going concerns. Common equity is more friendly to the recapitalization
viable as going concerns. Common equity is more friendly to the recapitalization
process than preferred stock because it is more junior and hence less problematic
process than preferred stock because it is more junior and hence less problematic
in terms of the debt overhang problem described above.
in terms of the debt overhang problem described above.
To see this point, consider two banks, A and B. Both begin with total assets of
To see this point, consider two banks, A and B. Both begin with total assets of
$100 and total capital of $6. But As capital is composed entirely of equity, while B
$100 and total capital of $6. But As capital is composed entirely of equity, while B
has $2 of equity and $4 of preferred. Now suppose both banks lose $3. To avoid
has $2 of equity and $4 of preferred. Now suppose both banks lose $3. To avoid
shrinking their assets, they would like to raise new capital. Suppose they do so by
shrinking their assets, they would like to raise new capital. Suppose they do so by
trying to issue equity. This will be harder for Bank B—whose entire pre-existing
trying to issue equity. This will be harder for Bank B—whose entire pre-existing
equity layer has been wiped out and whose preferred stock is, as a result, now trading
equity layer has been wiped out and whose preferred stock is, as a result, now trading
at a steep discount to its face value—for any new equity that B brings in will largely
at a steep discount to its face value—for any new equity that B brings in will largely
serve to bail out the position of its more senior preferred investors.
serve to bail out the position of its more senior preferred investors.
This logic suggests that given the goal of promoting rapid recapitalization by
This logic suggests that given the goal of promoting rapid recapitalization by
going-concern banks that run into trouble, it is entirely reasonable for regulators
going-concern banks that run into trouble, it is entirely reasonable for regulators
to require that most of the capital requirement be satis ed with common equity.
to require that most of the capital requirement be satis ed with common equity.
Indeed, one can argue that essentially
Indeed, one can argue that essentially all
of what is now the Tier 1 requirement
of what is now the Tier 1 requirement
should be in terms of equity, or instruments that are contractually guaranteed to
should be in terms of equity, or instruments that are contractually guaranteed to
convert into equity in a bad state (see below for a discussion), while more senior
convert into equity in a bad state (see below for a discussion), while more senior
securities like preferred stock should for the most part not count.
securities like preferred stock should for the most part not count.
10 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Corrective Action Targeted at Dollars of Capital, Not Capital Ratios
Corrective Action Targeted at Dollars of Capital, Not Capital Ratios
When regulators are vigilant, banks that fall below a designated capital threshold
When regulators are vigilant, banks that fall below a designated capital threshold
may be subject to a variety of sanctions (for example, restrictions on dividends)
may be subject to a variety of sanctions (for example, restrictions on dividends)
until they repair their capital ratios. The principle of rapid regulatory intervention
until they repair their capital ratios. The principle of rapid regulatory intervention
is undoubtedly a good one, but the form of the intervention matters a great deal.
is undoubtedly a good one, but the form of the intervention matters a great deal.
If a bank is put in the penalty box until it manages to  x its capital
If a bank is put in the penalty box until it manages to  x its capital ratio
, it may well
, it may well
choose to x the ratio not by raising the numerator (capital) but by reducing the
choose to  x the ratio not by raising the numerator (capital) but by reducing the
denominator (assets).
denominator (assets).
4
4
A better approach is to create incentives for the bank to raise
A better approach is to create incentives for the bank to raise
incremental dollars
of new capital.
of new capital.
One way to implement this policy would be with a capital ratio requirement that
One way to implement this policy would be with a capital ratio requirement that
refers to the
refers to the maximum
of current and lagged assets. Imagine a bank that starts with
of current and lagged assets. Imagine a bank that starts with
assets of $100 and capital of $8 at the end of year
assets of $100 and capital of $8 at the end of year
t
t
, and suppose that the threshold for
, and suppose that the threshold for
corrective action is a capital ratio of 6 percent. Now assume that the bank has losses of
corrective action is a capital ratio of 6 percent. Now assume that the bank has losses of
$4 over year
$4 over year t
+
+
1, so it ends the year with $4 of capital. Normally regulators would push
1, so it ends the year with $4 of capital. Normally regulators would push
the bank to get its ratio back to 6 percent, which it might do by shrinking its assets to
the bank to get its ratio back to 6 percent, which it might do by shrinking its assets to
$66.67. Under our alternative, the bank would only get out of the penalty box when
$66.67. Under our alternative, the bank would only get out of the penalty box when
its ratio of capital to the
its ratio of capital to the maximum of year t assets or year t
+
+ 1 assets
exceeded 6 percent.
exceeded 6 percent.
Given that year
Given that year t
assets were $100 and cannot be reduced retroactively, the bank would
assets were $100 and cannot be reduced retroactively, the bank would
have to raise $2 of new capital—it could not avoid sanctions by shrinking assets.
have to raise $2 of new capital—it could not avoid sanctions by shrinking assets.
A dramatic illustration of this dollars-based corrective action principle comes
A dramatic illustration of this dollars-based corrective action principle comes
from the Supervisory Capital Assessment Program (SCAP), the “stress tests” that
from the Supervisory Capital Assessment Program (SCAP), the “stress tests” that
the major U.S. banks underwent in spring 2009.
the major U.S. banks underwent in spring 2009.
5
5
The output of the SCAP was, for
The output of the SCAP was, for
each bank being tested, a
each bank being tested, a dollar
target for new equity capital that had to be raised,
target for new equity capital that had to be raised,
via equity issues or asset sales. For some of the banks involved, the numbers were
via equity issues or asset sales. For some of the banks involved, the numbers were
very large—for example, Bank of America was required to raise $33.5 billion. The
very large—for example, Bank of America was required to raise $33.5 billion. The
penalty box in this case was that any bank failing to raise the capital from the private
penalty box in this case was that any bank failing to raise the capital from the private
markets would be required to accept an equity injection from the Treasury, which
markets would be required to accept an equity injection from the Treasury, which
would have involved strict limits on executive compensation. Remarkably, in the
would have involved strict limits on executive compensation. Remarkably, in the
few weeks following the release of the SCAP results, the banks involved were able to
few weeks following the release of the SCAP results, the banks involved were able to
raise nearly $60 billion in new common equity; by the end of 2009 this gure had
raise nearly $60 billion in new common equity; by the end of 2009 this  gure had
risen to over $125 billion.
risen to over $125 billion.
Here is a case where a strong regulatory hand appears to have had highly
Here is a case where a strong regulatory hand appears to have had highly
bene cial effects. Indeed, by being tough and giving banks no choice, regulators
bene cial effects. Indeed, by being tough and giving banks no choice, regulators
probably made it easier for banks to do the capital raising. This is because absent
probably made it easier for banks to do the capital raising. This is because absent
discretion, the adverse selection problem normally associated with equity issues
discretion, the adverse selection problem normally associated with equity issues
disappears. If a bank has a choice of whether to issue equity, its decision to do so
disappears. If a bank has a choice of whether to issue equity, its decision to do so
may signal that management believes it to be overvalued, and hence this issuance
may signal that management believes it to be overvalued, and hence this issuance
may knock down the stock price (Myers and Majluf, 1984). But if it has no choice,
may knock down the stock price (Myers and Majluf, 1984). But if it has no choice,
4
Hart and Zingales (2010) recommend forcing banks to issue equity whenever their credit risk (as
measured by spreads on credit default swaps) goes above a certain level. However, this does not address
the shrinkage problem, because a bank can also reduce its credit spreads by selling risky assets.
5
See Hirtle, Schuermann, and Stiroh (2009) for a fuller discussion of the lessons learned from the SCAP.
A Macroprudential Approach to Financial Regulation 11
there is no information content, and hence no negative price impact. We hope that
there is no information content, and hence no negative price impact. We hope that
this lesson can be incorporated into regulatory policy going forward. As we note
this lesson can be incorporated into regulatory policy going forward. As we note
below, it may be especially helpful in thinking about the phase-in of higher capital
below, it may be especially helpful in thinking about the phase-in of higher capital
requirements under Basel III.
requirements under Basel III.
Contingent Capital
Contingent Capital
A dollars-based corrective action policy amounts to an attempt to force banks
A dollars-based corrective action policy amounts to an attempt to force banks
to recapitalize on the  y when they get into trouble. A closely related idea is to “pre-
to recapitalize on the  y when they get into trouble. A closely related idea is to “pre-
wire” the recapitalization with a contingent instrument that automatically increases
wire” the recapitalization with a contingent instrument that automatically increases
a bank’s equity position when some prespeci ed contractual provision is triggered.
a bank’s equity position when some prespeci ed contractual provision is triggered.
Two broad types of contingent capital instruments have been proposed. The rst,
Two broad types of contingent capital instruments have been proposed. The  rst,
sometimes called “reverse convertibles” or “contingent convertibles,involves a bank
sometimes called “reverse convertibles” or “contingent convertibles,” involves a bank
issuing a debt security that automatically converts into equity if a measure of either
issuing a debt security that automatically converts into equity if a measure of either
the bank’s regulatory capital or stock market value falls below a xed threshold
the bank’s regulatory capital or stock market value falls below a  xed threshold
(Flannery, 2005; French et al., 2010).
(Flannery, 2005; French et al., 2010).
6
6
For example, in November 2009, Lloyds Bank
For example, in November 2009, Lloyds Bank
issued £7.5 billion in contingent convertible debt, with conversion to equity to be
issued £7.5 billion in contingent convertible debt, with conversion to equity to be
triggered if Lloyds’ Tier 1 capital ratio falls below 5 percent.
triggered if Lloyds’ Tier 1 capital ratio falls below 5 percent.
A second type of contingent capital is “capital insurance,” which involves a bank
A second type of contingent capital is “capital insurance,” which involves a bank
purchasing an insurance policy that pays off in a bad state of the world (Kashyap,
purchasing an insurance policy that pays off in a bad state of the world (Kashyap,
Rajan, and Stein, 2008). To address concerns about the insurer defaulting, the policy
Rajan, and Stein, 2008). To address concerns about the insurer defaulting, the policy
would be fully collateralized—that is, the insurer would put the full amount of the
would be fully collateralized—that is, the insurer would put the full amount of the
policy into a lock-box up front. For example, a bank might contract with a pension
policy into a lock-box up front. For example, a bank might contract with a pension
fund to buy a capital insurance policy that pays $20 billion in the event that an econo-
fund to buy a capital insurance policy that pays $20 billion in the event that an econo-
mywide index of bank stock prices falls below some designated value any time in the
mywide index of bank stock prices falls below some designated value any time in the
next ve years. At initiation, the pension fund would turn the $20 billion over to a
next  ve years. At initiation, the pension fund would turn the $20 billion over to a
custodian; if the bad state is not realized within ve years, the $20 billion reverts back
custodian; if the bad state is not realized within  ve years, the $20 billion reverts back
to the pension fund, and if it is realized, the funds are transferred to the bank.
to the pension fund, and if it is realized, the funds are transferred to the bank.
These designs share a common motivation. The premise is that banks view
These designs share a common motivation. The premise is that banks view
equity capital as an expensive form of nance—in other words, there are one or
equity capital as an expensive form of  nance—in other words, there are one or
more violations of the Modigliani–Miller (1958) conditions that make banks reluc-
more violations of the Modigliani–Miller (1958) conditions that make banks reluc-
tant to carry large precautionary buffers of equity. (We discuss the precise nature
tant to carry large precautionary buffers of equity. (We discuss the precise nature
of these violations in detail below.) In principle, regulation could simply mandate
of these violations in detail below.) In principle, regulation could simply mandate
that banks maintain very large equity buffers. However, it may be more ef cient to
that banks maintain very large equity buffers. However, it may be more ef cient to
develop a  nancing arrangement that delivers more equity only in those bad states
develop a  nancing arrangement that delivers more equity only in those bad states
where it is most valuable.
where it is most valuable.
If these forms of contingent capital are such a good idea, why haven’t we seen
If these forms of contingent capital are such a good idea, why haven’t we seen
more of them? One simple answer is that they would have to be allowed to count
more of them? One simple answer is that they would have to be allowed to count
towards regulatory capital requirements. Consider the following approach. The
towards regulatory capital requirements. Consider the following approach. The
capital requirement for a bank in good times might be set at a relatively high level,
capital requirement for a bank in good times might be set at a relatively high level,
6
There are many important design issues associated with the speci cation of the trigger in a contingent
convertible security, with both pros and cons to using a trigger based on stock prices as opposed to
regulatory accounting numbers. See McDonald (2010) for a detailed discussion of these issues.
12 Journal of Economic Perspectives
say 20 percent. Banks would then be given a choice: they could satisfy the entire
say 20 percent. Banks would then be given a choice: they could satisfy the entire
requirement with equity, or they could satisfy up to say 10 percentage points of it
requirement with equity, or they could satisfy up to say 10 percentage points of it
with a reverse convertible so long as it was contractually guaranteed to turn into
with a reverse convertible so long as it was contractually guaranteed to turn into
equity in a well-de ned bad state. (As we discuss below, Swiss banking regulators
equity in a well-de ned bad state. (As we discuss below, Swiss banking regulators
recently announced new rules of exactly this form.) The reverse convertible might
recently announced new rules of exactly this form.) The reverse convertible might
be seen as more costly than straight debt—which is why banks would not use it if it
be seen as more costly than straight debt—which is why banks would not use it if it
did not count as regulatory capital—but as long as it was cheaper than equity, there
did not count as regulatory capital—but as long as it was cheaper than equity, there
would be an ef ciency gain.
would be an ef ciency gain.
Finally, it is worth noting the close connection between contingent capital and
Finally, it is worth noting the close connection between contingent capital and
proposals to reform executive compensation by imposing bonus holdbacks on key
proposals to reform executive compensation by imposing bonus holdbacks on key
employees of nancial rms. For example, French et al. (2010) suggest withholding
employees of  nancial rms. For example, French et al. (2010) suggest withholding
a signi cant share of each senior manager’s total compensation for several years.
a signi cant share of each senior manager’s total compensation for several years.
The withheld compensation would not take the form of stock or options, but would
The withheld compensation would not take the form of stock or options, but would
instead be a xed dollar amount. And, managers would forfeit their holdbacks if
instead be a  xed dollar amount. And, managers would forfeit their holdbacks if
the  rm were to fail or to receive extraordinary government assistance.
the  rm were to fail or to receive extraordinary government assistance.
Structurally, this holdback proposal is similar to the capital insurance scheme
Structurally, this holdback proposal is similar to the capital insurance scheme
of Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (2008), with the key difference being that it requires
of Kashyap, Rajan, and Stein (2008), with the key difference being that it requires
rm managers—rather than, say, a pension fund—to be the insurance provider.
rm managers—rather than, say, a pension fund—to be the insurance provider.
The merit of this approach is that not only does the held-back compensation
The merit of this approach is that not only does the held-back compensation
create an extra, contingent capital buffer, it also helps to improve incentives
create an extra, contingent capital buffer, it also helps to improve incentives
within the rm. In particular, by making insiders bear downside risk without any
within the  rm. In particular, by making insiders bear downside risk without any
additional upside potential, it aligns their fortunes with those of taxpayers and
additional upside potential, it aligns their fortunes with those of taxpayers and
other creditors—and in so doing, leans against the heads I win, tails you lose”
other creditors—and in so doing, leans against the “heads I win, tails you lose”
risk-taking incentives created by more conventional forms of stock- and pro t-
risk-taking incentives created by more conventional forms of stock- and pro t-
linked compensation.
linked compensation.
Regulation of Debt Maturity
Regulation of Debt Maturity
One important lesson from the recent crisis is that the distinction between
One important lesson from the recent crisis is that the distinction between
short-term and long-term debt had been given insuf cient attention by regula-
short-term and long-term debt had been given insuf cient attention by regula-
tors.
tors.
Table 2 presents a snapshot of the aggregate liability structure of the U.S.
Table 2 presents a snapshot of the aggregate liability structure of the U.S.
banking system, including not only traditional commercial banks but also broker-
banking system, including not only traditional commercial banks but also broker-
dealer  rms. Clearly, the majority of their debt is short-term: either in the form of
dealer  rms. Clearly, the majority of their debt is short-term: either in the form of
deposits or “wholesale” funding, which includes commercial paper and repurchase
deposits or “wholesale” funding, which includes commercial paper and repurchase
(repo) agreements. While deposits are generally insured and hence not likely to
(repo) agreements. While deposits are generally insured and hence not likely to
run at the  rst sign of trouble, the same is not true for wholesale funding. Indeed,
run at the  rst sign of trouble, the same is not true for wholesale funding. Indeed,
wholesale funding runs—a refusal of repo and commercial paper creditors to roll
wholesale funding runs—a refusal of repo and commercial paper creditors to roll
over their loans—played a key role in the demise of Northern Rock, Bear Stearns,
over their loans—played a key role in the demise of Northern Rock, Bear Stearns,
and Lehman Brothers, among other high-pro le failures (Shin, 2009; Gorton and
and Lehman Brothers, among other high-pro le failures (Shin, 2009; Gorton and
Metrick, 2010; Duf e, 2010).
Metrick, 2010; Duf e, 2010).
The case for regulating the use of short-term debt by nancial rms—above
The case for regulating the use of short-term debt by  nancial rms—above
and beyond regulating total leverage—rests on two observations. First, the ability of
and beyond regulating total leverage—rests on two observations. First, the ability of
short-term lenders to run leads to more fragility than in the case with an equivalent
short-term lenders to run leads to more fragility than in the case with an equivalent
amount of long-term debt (Diamond and Dybvig, 1983). It is hard to imagine that
amount of long-term debt (Diamond and Dybvig, 1983). It is hard to imagine that
Samuel G. Hanson, Anil K Kashyap, and Jeremy C. Stein 13
Northern Rock, or Bear Stearns, or Lehman would have faced the same problems
Northern Rock, or Bear Stearns, or Lehman would have faced the same problems
had they done most of their borrowing on a long-term basis. Second, in the pres-
had they done most of their borrowing on a long-term basis. Second, in the pres-
ence of marketwide re sales, the choice of debt maturity creates an externality.
ence of marketwide  re sales, the choice of debt maturity creates an externality.
When an individual bank or broker-dealer opts to nance largely with short-term
When an individual bank or broker-dealer opts to  nance largely with short-term
debt, it fails to internalize that in a crisis, an inability to roll over short-term debt
debt, it fails to internalize that in a crisis, an inability to roll over short-term debt
will force it to liquidate assets, thereby imposing a re-sale cost on others who
will force it to liquidate assets, thereby imposing a  re-sale cost on others who
hold the same assets and who see the value of their own collateral diminished. The
hold the same assets and who see the value of their own collateral diminished. The
result is a level of short-term nancing that is socially excessive—hence the role for
result is a level of short-term  nancing that is socially excessive—hence the role for
regulation (Stein, 2010a).
regulation (Stein, 2010a).
Regulating the Shadow Banking System
Regulating the Shadow Banking System
The  re-sale risk associated with excessive short-term funding comes from not
The  re-sale risk associated with excessive short-term funding comes from not
just insured depositories, but rather, any nancial intermediary whose combina-
just insured depositories, but rather, any  nancial intermediary whose combina-
tion of asset choice and nancing structure may exacerbate a systemic re-sale
tion of asset choice and  nancing structure may exacerbate a systemic  re-sale
problem. A narrow interpretation of this principle would say that regulation should
problem. A narrow interpretation of this principle would say that regulation should
cover large, systemically signi cant nonbank institutions such as Bear Stearns and
cover large, systemically signi cant nonbank institutions such as Bear Stearns and
Table 2
Liability Structure of U.S. Bank Holding Companies, 2009
$ trillion % of assets
Assets 15.927 100.0%
Liabilities
Deposits 7.502 47.1%
Short-term wholesale funding
Repurchase agreements and federal funds purchased 1.658 10.4%
Other short-term wholesale funding 0.880 5.5%
Trading liabilities 0.736 4.6%
Total 3.274 20.6%
Long-term funding
Long-term wholesale funding 1.718 10.8%
Subordinated debt and trust preferred 0.416 2.6%
Total 2.134 13.4%
Other liabilities 1.570 9.9%
Total liabilities 14.480 90.9%
Equity
Common stock 1.309 8.2%
Preferred stock 0.137 0.9%
Total equity 1.446 9.1%
Sources: The table is based on data from the FR Y-9C reports that Bank Holding Companies are required
to  le with the Federal Reserve.
Note: This table summarizes the liability structure of U.S. bank holding companies as of December 31,
2009.
14 Journal of Economic Perspectives
Lehman Brothers, who did not nance themselves with insured deposits but who
Lehman Brothers, who did not  nance themselves with insured deposits but who
were nevertheless subject to wholesale nancing runs. While this speci c point is
were nevertheless subject to wholesale  nancing runs. While this speci c point is
now well appreciated, the principle has broader application. From the perspective
now well appreciated, the principle has broader application. From the perspective
of credit creation and macroeconomic impact, some of the most damaging aspects
of credit creation and macroeconomic impact, some of the most damaging aspects
of the crisis arose not just from the problems of individual large rms, but also from
of the crisis arose not just from the problems of individual large  rms, but also from
the
the collapse of an entire market
—namely the market for asset-backed securities.
—namely the market for asset-backed securities.
Figure 1 illustrates this collapse.
Figure 1 illustrates this collapse.
7
7
The market for “traditional” asset-backed secu-
The market for “traditional” asset-backed secu-
rities, those based on credit-card, auto, and student loans, averaged between $50 and
rities, those based on credit-card, auto, and student loans, averaged between $50 and
$70 billion of new issues per quarter in the years prior to the crisis (total issuance for
$70 billion of new issues per quarter in the years prior to the crisis (total issuance for
2007 was $238 billion). However, in the last quarter of 2008, following the demise
2007 was $238 billion). However, in the last quarter of 2008, following the demise
of Lehman, issues in this category fell to just over $2 billion. The disappearance of
of Lehman, issues in this category fell to just over $2 billion. The disappearance of
this market represented a major contraction in the supply of credit to consumers.
this market represented a major contraction in the supply of credit to consumers.
The investors who buy tranches of asset-backed securities frequently do so
The investors who buy tranches of asset-backed securities frequently do so
by relying on short-term borrowing. Entities known as “structured investment
by relying on short-term borrowing. Entities known as “structured investment
vehicles” or “conduits,” which in the past tended to be af liated with sponsoring
vehicles” or “conduits,” which in the past tended to be af liated with sponsoring
7
The discussion in the remainder of this section is a much-abridged version of material in Stein (2010b).
Figure 1
Quarterly Issuance of Asset-Backed Securities, 2000–2010Q2
Source: The data underlying this  gure come from Thompson SDC.
Notes: The  gure plots the quarterly issuance of traditional versus nontraditional asset-backed securities
(ABS). Traditional ABS includes securitizations backed by auto loans, credit card receivables, and
student loans. Nontraditional issuance includes ABS backed by subprime mortgages, collateralized debt
obligations (CDOs), and collateralized loan obligations (CLOs). While the nontraditional category
includes securitizations backed by subprime mortgages, it does not include securitizations backed by
prime mortgages, such as mortgage-backed securities guaranteed by Fannie Mae or Freddie Mac.
350
300
$ billion
250
200
150
100
50
0
Mar. 00
Mar. 01
Mar. 02
Mar. 03
Mar. 04
Mar. 06
Mar. 05
Mar. 10
Mar. 09
Mar. 08
Mar. 07
Traditional (auto, credit cards, student loans)
Nontraditional (subprime, CDOs, CLOs)
A Macroprudential Approach to Financial Regulation 15
commercial banks, hold tranches of asset-backed securities and  nance them with
commercial banks, hold tranches of asset-backed securities and  nance them with
commercial paper, which typically has a maturity of only days or weeks. Hedge
commercial paper, which typically has a maturity of only days or weeks. Hedge
funds and broker-dealer  rms may nance their holdings of asset-backed securities
funds and broker-dealer  rms may nance their holdings of asset-backed securities
with repurchase agreements, a form of overnight collateralized borrowing. Collec-
with repurchase agreements, a form of overnight collateralized borrowing. Collec-
tively, these various investors who acquire asset-backed securities and nance them
tively, these various investors who acquire asset-backed securities and  nance them
with short-term debt are often referred to as the
with short-term debt are often referred to as the shadow banking system
. Moreover,
. Moreover,
as emphasized by Gorton (2010), Gorton and Metrick (2010), and Covitz, Liang,
as emphasized by Gorton (2010), Gorton and Metrick (2010), and Covitz, Liang,
and Suarez (2009), the collapse of the asset-backed securities market featured the
and Suarez (2009), the collapse of the asset-backed securities market featured the
essential elements of a classic bank run—namely an inability of investors in asset-
essential elements of a classic bank run—namely an inability of investors in asset-
backed securities to roll over short-term  nancing.
backed securities to roll over short-term  nancing.
One manifestation of the withdrawal of short-term lending to the asset-backed
One manifestation of the withdrawal of short-term lending to the asset-backed
securities market comes from the behavior of “haircuts” in repurchase agreements.
securities market comes from the behavior of “haircuts” in repurchase agreements.
When an investor borrows in the repo market, the investor is required to post a
When an investor borrows in the repo market, the investor is required to post a
margin, or down payment, known as the “haircut.” Haircuts on most highly rated
margin, or down payment, known as the “haircut.” Haircuts on most highly rated
asset-backed securities were very low prior to the crisis, on the order of 2 percent.
asset-backed securities were very low prior to the crisis, on the order of 2 percent.
Thus, if a hedge fund wanted to buy $1 billion of AAA-rated, auto-linked asset-
Thus, if a hedge fund wanted to buy $1 billion of AAA-rated, auto-linked asset-
backed securities, it only needed to put up $20 million of its own capital. The other
backed securities, it only needed to put up $20 million of its own capital. The other
$980 million could be borrowed on an overnight basis in the repo market; in many
$980 million could be borrowed on an overnight basis in the repo market; in many
cases the ultimate lenders were money-market mutual funds.
cases the ultimate lenders were money-market mutual funds.
8
8
In the midst of the crisis, haircuts skyrocketed. Even haircuts on consumer
In the midst of the crisis, haircuts skyrocketed. Even haircuts on consumer
asset-backed securities—which were not linked to subprime problems—rose to over
asset-backed securities—which were not linked to subprime problems—rose to over
50 percent. From the perspective of the hedge fund holding $1 billion of such
50 percent. From the perspective of the hedge fund holding $1 billion of such
securities, all of a sudden it could only borrow $500 million, and instead of having to
securities, all of a sudden it could only borrow $500 million, and instead of having to
post a $20 million down payment, had to put up $500 million. If it did not have the
post a $20 million down payment, had to put up $500 million. If it did not have the
cash to do so, it would be forced to liquidate its holdings. These liquidations, and
cash to do so, it would be forced to liquidate its holdings. These liquidations, and
the effect they had on the level and volatility of prices, in turn justi ed the increased
the effect they had on the level and volatility of prices, in turn justi ed the increased
skittishness of the lenders in the repo market, since their protection depends on
skittishness of the lenders in the repo market, since their protection depends on
the collateral value of the assets they lend against. In other words, the disruption to
the collateral value of the assets they lend against. In other words, the disruption to
the asset-backed securities market may have been what Brunnermeier and Pedersen
the asset-backed securities market may have been what Brunnermeier and Pedersen
(2009) call a “margin spiral.”
(2009) call a “margin spiral.”
From a macroprudential perspective, it would be a mistake to focus too
From a macroprudential perspective, it would be a mistake to focus too
narrowly on the largest nancial institutions while paying insuf cient attention
narrowly on the largest  nancial institutions while paying insuf cient attention
to potential vulnerabilities in the rest of the system.
to potential vulnerabilities in the rest of the system.
9
9
What concrete steps might
What concrete steps might
be taken in this regard? A useful  rst principle is that an effort should be made to
be taken in this regard? A useful  rst principle is that an effort should be made to
impose similar capital standards on a given type of credit exposure irrespective of
impose similar capital standards on a given type of credit exposure irrespective of
8
This is not to say that the hedge fund’s overall leverage would be 50 to 1, as in this example—only that
it could borrow aggressively against certain highly rated assets that were seen as low risk and hence as
very good collateral.
9
Some have advocated a “narrow banking” model, whereby tightly regulated banks are restricted to
core deposit-taking and lending activities, and a substantial chunk of their other business is pushed out
to a more lightly regulated periphery. While such an approach may keep certain functions (such as the
payments system) safe, the risk is that the overall process of credit creation may be made more vulner-
able, not less, to shutdown in the event of a crisis.
16 Journal of Economic Perspectives
who winds up ultimately holding the exposure—be it a bank, broker-dealer, hedge
who winds up ultimately holding the exposure—be it a bank, broker-dealer, hedge
fund, or special purpose vehicle. This task is not easy, but one tool that would help
fund, or special purpose vehicle. This task is not easy, but one tool that would help
is broad-based regulation of haircuts on asset-backed securities.
is broad-based regulation of haircuts on asset-backed securities.
10
10
Consider the case where the exposure is a consumer loan. If this loan is made
Consider the case where the exposure is a consumer loan. If this loan is made
by a bank, it will be subject to a capital requirement. Now suppose instead that
by a bank, it will be subject to a capital requirement. Now suppose instead that
the loan is securitized by the bank and becomes part of a consumer asset-backed
the loan is securitized by the bank and becomes part of a consumer asset-backed
security whose tranches are distributed to investors. The regulation we have in mind
security whose tranches are distributed to investors. The regulation we have in mind
would stipulate that whoever holds a tranche of the asset-backed security would
would stipulate that whoever holds a tranche of the asset-backed security would
be required to post and maintain a minimum haircut against that tranche—with
be required to post and maintain a minimum haircut against that tranche—with
the value of the haircut depending on the seniority of the tranche, the quality of
the value of the haircut depending on the seniority of the tranche, the quality of
the underlying collateral, and so forth. Such a requirement is nothing conceptually
the underlying collateral, and so forth. Such a requirement is nothing conceptually
new and should not be dif cult to enforce; indeed, it is closely analogous to the
new and should not be dif cult to enforce; indeed, it is closely analogous to the
initial and maintenance margin requirements that are currently applicable to inves-
initial and maintenance margin requirements that are currently applicable to inves-
tors in common stocks. For models that suggest a role for haircut regulation, see
tors in common stocks. For models that suggest a role for haircut regulation, see
Geanakoplos (2010) and Stein (2010a).
Geanakoplos (2010) and Stein (2010a).
If these requirements are well-structured, they would have two bene ts. First,
If these requirements are well-structured, they would have two bene ts. First,
they could help to harmonize regulation across organizational forms, thereby
they could help to harmonize regulation across organizational forms, thereby
reducing the incentive for lending activity to migrate into the shadow banking
reducing the incentive for lending activity to migrate into the shadow banking
sector. Second, for those assets that do end up in the shadow banking system,
sector. Second, for those assets that do end up in the shadow banking system,
haircut regulation can dampen the destabilizing dynamics described above. If hair-
haircut regulation can dampen the destabilizing dynamics described above. If hair-
cuts start out at 2 percent and then jump to 50 percent in a crisis, this creates a
cuts start out at 2 percent and then jump to 50 percent in a crisis, this creates a
powerful forced-selling pressure on owners of asset-backed securities. If haircuts are
powerful forced-selling pressure on owners of asset-backed securities. If haircuts are
set instead at a higher value before the crisis, this forced-selling mechanism and the
set instead at a higher value before the crisis, this forced-selling mechanism and the
vicious spiral it unleashes might be attenuated. Note that central banks, through
vicious spiral it unleashes might be attenuated. Note that central banks, through
their discount window and emergency-lending facilities, have already developed
their discount window and emergency-lending facilities, have already developed
signi cant expertise in determining prudent values of haircuts on various kinds of
signi cant expertise in determining prudent values of haircuts on various kinds of
asset-backed securities.
asset-backed securities.
While we have focused on regulations that address re-sale externalities, the
While we have focused on regulations that address  re-sale externalities, the
problems of the asset-backed securities market arguably go beyond re sales. Hanson
problems of the asset-backed securities market arguably go beyond  re sales. Hanson
and Sunderam (2010) show that the “tranching” process, by which large fractions
and Sunderam (2010) show that the “tranching” process, by which large fractions
of underlying collateral pools are turned into AAA-rated securities, can blunt the
of underlying collateral pools are turned into AAA-rated securities, can blunt the
incentives of investors to become informed about what they are buying—because
incentives of investors to become informed about what they are buying—because
AAA-rated securities are ostensibly so low risk that the returns to becoming informed
AAA-rated securities are ostensibly so low risk that the returns to becoming informed
are minimal. A lack of informed investors can in turn make securitization markets
are minimal. A lack of informed investors can in turn make securitization markets
more fragile when times turn bad and the need to analyze securitization cash ows
more fragile when times turn bad and the need to analyze securitization cash  ows
rises. This implies that regulators should worry about the structure of securitiza-
rises. This implies that regulators should worry about the structure of securitiza-
tions—particularly the amount of AAA-rated securities being manufactured from
tions—particularly the amount of AAA-rated securities being manufactured from
any given collateral pool.
any given collateral pool.
10
A more general version of this observation is that a regulatory toolkit with only a capital ratio and a
single liquidity ratio will be inadequate for controlling instability arising from deposit defaults,  re sales,
and credit crunches (Kashyap, Berner, and Goodhart, forthcoming).
Samuel G. Hanson, Anil K Kashyap, and Jeremy C. Stein 17
What Are the Costs of Higher Capital Requirements?
What Are the Costs of Higher Capital Requirements?
We have argued that a macroprudential approach involves imposing substan-
We have argued that a macroprudential approach involves imposing substan-
tially higher capital requirements on nancial rms, particularly in good times.
tially higher capital requirements on  nancial rms, particularly in good times.
But will these higher capital requirements lead to increased costs for borrowers? In
But will these higher capital requirements lead to increased costs for borrowers? In
what follows, we focus on the long-run steady-state consequences of higher capital
what follows, we focus on the long-run steady-state consequences of higher capital
requirements, setting aside the transitional issues associated with phase-in of a new
requirements, setting aside the transitional issues associated with phase-in of a new
regime.
regime.
11
11
To preview, our reading of the theory and relevant empirical evidence
To preview, our reading of the theory and relevant empirical evidence
suggests that while increased capital requirements might be expected to have some
suggests that while increased capital requirements might be expected to have some
long-run impact on the cost of loans, this effect is likely to be quite small.
long-run impact on the cost of loans, this effect is likely to be quite small.
A Modigliani–Miller Perspective
A Modigliani–Miller Perspective
Modigliani and Miller (1958) famously showed that under certain conditions, a
Modigliani and Miller (1958) famously showed that under certain conditions, a
rm’s capital structure is irrelevant for its operating decisions. In the banking context,
rm’s capital structure is irrelevant for its operating decisions. In the banking context,
this would imply that the rate that a rm charges on its loans should be
this would imply that the rate that a  rm charges on its loans should be independent
of its capital ratio. The Modigliani and Miller conditions are stringent, including
of its capital ratio. The Modigliani and Miller conditions are stringent, including
no taxes, symmetric information, rational risk-based pricing, and cash ows that are
no taxes, symmetric information, rational risk-based pricing, and cash ows that are
independent of nancial policy. Thus, they are not meant as an accurate depiction
independent of  nancial policy. Thus, they are not meant as an accurate depiction
of reality. Rather, the value of the Modigliani and Miller framework is that it forces
of reality. Rather, the value of the Modigliani and Miller framework is that it forces
one to be precise about which of the conditions is violated, and this allows for a more
one to be precise about which of the conditions is violated, and this allows for a more
disciplined analysis of the effects associated with changes in capital structure.
disciplined analysis of the effects associated with changes in capital structure.
In particular, the Modigliani and Miller paradigm exposes the aw in the
In particular, the Modigliani and Miller paradigm exposes the  aw in the
following reasoning: “Equity is more expensive than debt because it is riskier. Thus,
following reasoning: “Equity is more expensive than debt because it is riskier. Thus,
if a bank is forced to rely more on equity, its overall cost of nance will go up, and
if a bank is forced to rely more on equity, its overall cost of  nance will go up, and
it will have to charge more for its loans.” The fallacy here is that the risk of equity,
it will have to charge more for its loans.” The fallacy here is that the risk of equity,
and hence its required return, is not a constant, but rather declines as leverage
and hence its required return, is not a constant, but rather declines as leverage
falls.
falls.
12
12
Indeed, when all the Modigliani and Miller conditions hold, this effect is just
Indeed, when all the Modigliani and Miller conditions hold, this effect is just
enough to offset the increased weight of the more-expensive equity in the capital
enough to offset the increased weight of the more-expensive equity in the capital
structure so that the overall cost of capital
structure so that the overall cost of capital stays  xed
as bank leverage varies.
as bank leverage varies.
With this caveat in mind, we discuss two deviations from Modigliani and
With this caveat in mind, we discuss two deviations from Modigliani and
Miller’s idealized conditions that are likely to be relevant in the present context.
Miller’s idealized conditions that are likely to be relevant in the present context.
First, interest payments on corporate debt are tax deductible while dividend
First, interest payments on corporate debt are tax deductible while dividend
payments on equity are not. This effect lends itself to easy measurement. Suppose
payments on equity are not. This effect lends itself to easy measurement. Suppose
that new equity capital displaces
that new equity capital displaces long-term
debt in a bank’s capital structure and
debt in a bank’s capital structure and
that the only effect on the bank’s weighted average cost of capital comes from the
that the only effect on the bank’s weighted average cost of capital comes from the
lost tax shields on the debt. If the coupon on the debt is 7 percent, and given a
lost tax shields on the debt. If the coupon on the debt is 7 percent, and given a
corporate tax rate of 35 percent, each percentage point of increased equity raises
corporate tax rate of 35 percent, each percentage point of increased equity raises
11
This section draws on material from our unpublished working paper, Kashyap, Stein, and Hanson
(2010).
12
In Kashyap, Stein, and Hanson (2010), we show that this holds empirically in the banking sector: in a
panel of large banks, those with less leverage have signi cantly lower values of both beta and stock-return
volatility.
18 Journal of Economic Perspectives
the weighted average cost of capital by .07
the weighted average cost of capital by .07
×
×
.35
.35
=
=
.0245 percent, or 2.45 basis
.0245 percent, or 2.45 basis
points. Thus, even a 10 percentage-point increase in the capital requirement only
points. Thus, even a 10 percentage-point increase in the capital requirement only
boosts the weighted average cost of capital—and hence loan rates—by 25 basis
boosts the weighted average cost of capital—and hence loan rates—by 25 basis
points, which is a small effect.
points, which is a small effect.
To generate a higher gure, consider a case where equity displaces
To generate a higher  gure, consider a case where equity displaces short-
term
debt; this can be interpreted as capturing the joint effects of an increase
debt; this can be interpreted as capturing the joint effects of an increase
in both capital and liquidity requirements. Moreover, following Gorton (2010),
in both capital and liquidity requirements. Moreover, following Gorton (2010),
Gorton and Metrick (2010), and Stein (2010a), assume that—in violation of the
Gorton and Metrick (2010), and Stein (2010a), assume that—in violation of the
Modigliani and Miller conditions—there is a non-risk-based “money” premium
Modigliani and Miller conditions—there is a non-risk-based “money” premium
on wholesale short-term bank debt that re ects its usefulness as a transactions
on wholesale short-term bank debt that re ects its usefulness as a transactions
medium. (Commercial paper and repo are often held by money-market mutual
medium. (Commercial paper and repo are often held by money-market mutual
funds, who in turn issue checkable deposits.) An upper-bound estimate of this
funds, who in turn issue checkable deposits.) An upper-bound estimate of this
money premium might be on the order of 100 basis points.
money premium might be on the order of 100 basis points.
13
13
Now, a 10 percentage-
Now, a 10 percentage-
point increase in capital requirements raises the weighted average cost of capital
point increase in capital requirements raises the weighted average cost of capital
by an added 10 basis points relative to the previous taxes-only case, and we are up
by an added 10 basis points relative to the previous taxes-only case, and we are up
to 35 basis points. This number is still quite modest.
to 35 basis points. This number is still quite modest.
Time Variation in Bank Capital Ratios and Lending Rates
Time Variation in Bank Capital Ratios and Lending Rates
Our calibrations based on the Modigliani–Miller paradigm suggest that the
Our calibrations based on the Modigliani–Miller paradigm suggest that the
long-run effects of higher capital requirements on loan rates should be small. A
long-run effects of higher capital requirements on loan rates should be small. A
complementary approach is to examine the historical record. Figure 2A, which is
complementary approach is to examine the historical record. Figure 2A, which is
adapted from Berger, Herring, and Szego (1995), shows the ratio of book equity to
adapted from Berger, Herring, and Szego (1995), shows the ratio of book equity to
book assets for U.S. commercial banks from 1840 to 2009. Capital ratios exceeded
book assets for U.S. commercial banks from 1840 to 2009. Capital ratios exceeded
50 percent in the 1840s and fell steadily for the next 100 years, reaching 6 percent
50 percent in the 1840s and fell steadily for the next 100 years, reaching 6 percent
by the 1940s. Have these large uctuations in capital ratios translated into big differ-
by the 1940s. Have these large  uctuations in capital ratios translated into big differ-
ences in the cost of bank credit? To address this question, we have examined the
ences in the cost of bank credit? To address this question, we have examined the
behavior of various proxies for the markup that banks charge on loans. In a variety
behavior of various proxies for the markup that banks charge on loans. In a variety
of regression speci cations (not shown here), we found no reliable time-series
of regression speci cations (not shown here), we found no reliable time-series
correlation between these markup variables and bank capital ratios. The historical
correlation between these markup variables and bank capital ratios. The historical
data is simply too noisy, and our proxies for loan spreads too crude, for us to draw
data is simply too noisy, and our proxies for loan spreads too crude, for us to draw
any con dent conclusions about whether a correlation between equity ratios and
any con dent conclusions about whether a correlation between equity ratios and
loan rates
loan rates even exists
.
.
To illustrate the loose ties between loan costs and capital ratios, Figure 2B
To illustrate the loose ties between loan costs and capital ratios, Figure 2B
plots capital ratios for the period 1920–2009 against two markup proxies: 1) the
plots capital ratios for the period 1920–2009 against two markup proxies: 1) the
net interest margin (net interest income over earning assets); and 2) the yield on
net interest margin (net interest income over earning assets); and 2) the yield on
loans (interest income on loans over gross loans) minus the rate paid on deposits
loans (interest income on loans over gross loans) minus the rate paid on deposits
(interest expense on deposits over deposits). As can be seen, there is no apparent
(interest expense on deposits over deposits). As can be seen, there is no apparent
correlation between capital ratios and either measure of markups.
correlation between capital ratios and either measure of markups.
13
As a benchmark, Krishnamurthy and Vissing-Jorgensen (2010) estimate that Treasury securities
impound a money-like convenience premium of approximately 72 basis points, on top of what would be
expected in a standard risk-vs.-return asset-pricing setting.
A Macroprudential Approach to Financial Regulation 19
Figure 2
U.S. Bank Capital Ratios and Loan Spreads
Sources: Data from 1840 to 1896 is based on Berger, Herring, and Szego (1995) who use data from the
Statistical Abstracts of the United States. Data from 1896 to 1919 is based on data for “All Banks” from the All
Bank Statistics, 1896–1955 (Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve, 1959). Data from 1919 to 1933 is
based on Federal Reserve member banks and is from Banking and Monetary Statistics, 1919–1941 (Board
of Governors of the Federal Reserve, 1943). Data from 1934 to 2010 is for all insured commercial banks
and is from the FDIC’s Historical Statistics on Banking.
Notes: Figure 2A plots the ratio of book equity to book assets for U.S. commercial banks from 1840 to
2009. Figure 2B plots two measures of bank loan spreads versus equity/assets from 1920 to 2009. We
measure loan spreads using either the net interest margin (net interest income over earning assets)
or the yield on loans minus the rate paid on deposits (interest income on loans over gross loans minus
interest expense on deposits over deposits).
A: Book Equity to Assets for U.S. Banks, 1840–2009
B: Relationship between Loan Spreads and Bank Equity/Assets, 1920–2009
60%
0%
50%
40%
30%
20%
10%
1840
2010
1850
1860
1870
1880
1890
1900
1910
1920
1930
1940
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
4%
16%
14%
12%
10%
8%
6%
1%
7%
6%
5%
4%
3%
2%
1920
2010
1930
1940
1950
1960
1970
1980
1990
2000
Bank equity/assets (left scale)
Bank net interest margins (right scale)
Bank loan yield - Deposit rate (right scale)
Equity to assets
20 Journal of Economic Perspectives
But Then Why Are Banks So Determined to Operate with High Leverage?
But Then Why Are Banks So Determined to Operate with High Leverage?
These conclusions may appear surprising, even paradoxical. If signi cant
These conclusions may appear surprising, even paradoxical. If signi cant
increases in capital ratios have only small consequences for the rates that banks
increases in capital ratios have only small consequences for the rates that banks
charge their customers, why do banks generally feel compelled to operate in
charge their customers, why do banks generally feel compelled to operate in
such a highly leveraged fashion in spite of the risks this poses? And why do they
such a highly leveraged fashion in spite of the risks this poses? And why do they
deploy armies of lobbyists to ght increases in their capital requirements? After
deploy armies of lobbyists to  ght increases in their capital requirements? After
all, non nancial rms tend to operate with much less leverage and indeed appear
all, non nancial  rms tend to operate with much less leverage and indeed appear
willing in many cases to forego the tax (or other) bene ts of debt nance altogether.
willing in many cases to forego the tax (or other) bene ts of debt  nance altogether.
In Kashyap, Stein, and Hanson (2010), we argue that the resolution of this
In Kashyap, Stein, and Hanson (2010), we argue that the resolution of this
puzzle has to do with the nature of competition in nancial services. The most
puzzle has to do with the nature of competition in  nancial services. The most
important competitive edge that banks bring to bear for many types of transactions
important competitive edge that banks bring to bear for many types of transactions
is the ability to fund themselves cheaply. Thus, if Bank A is forced to adopt a capital
is the ability to fund themselves cheaply. Thus, if Bank A is forced to adopt a capital
structure that raises its cost of funding relative to other intermediaries by 20 basis
structure that raises its cost of funding relative to other intermediaries by 20 basis
points, it may lose most of its business, (or become much less pro table, since the
points, it may lose most of its business, (or become much less pro table, since the
return on assets in banking is on the order of 125 basis points). Contrast this with,
return on assets in banking is on the order of 125 basis points). Contrast this with,
say, the auto industry, where cheap nancing is only one of many possible sources
say, the auto industry, where cheap  nancing is only one of many possible sources
of advantage: a strong brand, quality engineering and customer service, and control
of advantage: a strong brand, quality engineering and customer service, and control
over labor costs may all be vastly more important than a 20 basis-point difference in
over labor costs may all be vastly more important than a 20 basis-point difference in
the cost of capital.
the cost of capital.
One suggestive piece of evidence for this competition hypothesis comes from
One suggestive piece of evidence for this competition hypothesis comes from
the distribution of capital ratios by bank size, as illustrated in Figure 3, which covers
the distribution of capital ratios by bank size, as illustrated in Figure 3, which covers
the period 1976–2009. There is a strong inverse relationship between bank size
the period 1976–2009. There is a strong inverse relationship between bank size
and capital ratios, with the smallest banks (with assets under $100 million) having
and capital ratios, with the smallest banks (with assets under $100 million) having
Tier 1 risk-based capital ratios more than double those of the largest banks (with
Tier 1 risk-based capital ratios more than double those of the largest banks (with
assets over $100 billion) for most of the sample period. Whatever their root cause,
assets over $100 billion) for most of the sample period. Whatever their root cause,
these large differences in capital ratios hint at a couple of important points. First,
these large differences in capital ratios hint at a couple of important points. First,
they suggest that several percentage points of additional capital need not imply
they suggest that several percentage points of additional capital need not imply
prohibitively large effects on lending rates—for if they did, it would be hard to
prohibitively large effects on lending rates—for if they did, it would be hard to
understand how the smaller community banks have managed to stay in business.
understand how the smaller community banks have managed to stay in business.
Second, the ability of small banks to survive at higher capital levels probably re ects
Second, the ability of small banks to survive at higher capital levels probably re ects
something about the softer degree of competition in their core line of business. A
something about the softer degree of competition in their core line of business. A
large literature argues that small banks tend to focus on informationally intensive
large literature argues that small banks tend to focus on informationally intensive
“relationship lending” and that the embedded soft information in these relation-
“relationship lending” and that the embedded soft information in these relation-
ships creates a degree of speci city between rms and their lenders (Rajan, 1992;
ships creates a degree of speci city between  rms and their lenders (Rajan, 1992;
Petersen and Rajan, 1994, 1995; Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and Stein, 2005).
Petersen and Rajan, 1994, 1995; Berger, Miller, Petersen, Rajan, and Stein, 2005).
To the extent that larger banks deal with larger customers where competition from
To the extent that larger banks deal with larger customers where competition from
other providers of nance is more intense, even small cost-of-capital disadvantages
other providers of  nance is more intense, even small cost-of-capital disadvantages
are likely to prove unsustainable.
are likely to prove unsustainable.
Testing the Competition Hypothesis
Testing the Competition Hypothesis
To further investigate the competition hypothesis, we examine the effects of
To further investigate the competition hypothesis, we examine the effects of
changes in state branching regulations. We test two basic predictions. First, we expect
changes in state branching regulations. We test two basic predictions. First, we expect
that a regulatory shock that increases the degree of competition in a state should
that a regulatory shock that increases the degree of competition in a state should
Samuel G. Hanson, Anil K Kashyap, and Jeremy C. Stein 21
Figure 3
U.S. Bank Capital Ratios by Bank Size, 1976–2009
Source: The  gure is based on data from bank Call Reports.
Notes: This  gure plots capital ratios by bank size from 1976–2009. Banks are placed into size groups
based on assets in 2008Q4 dollars. Figure 3A plots book equity to book assets. Figure 3B plots Tier
1 capital ratios (Tier 1 regulatory capital over risk-weighted assets). All banks owned by a given bank
holding company are combined into a single organization for the purposes of this size classi cation.
A: Book Equity to Book Assets
B: Tier 1 Risk-Based Capital Ratios
2%
4%
6%
8%
10%
12%
14%
1976
1978
1980
1982
1984
1986
1988
1990
1992
1994
1996
1998
2000
2002
2004
2006
2008
Assets < $100m
$10B < Assets < $100B
8%
10%
12%
14%
16%
18%
20%
6%
1996
1997
1998
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
$1B < Assets < $10B
$100m < Assets < $1B
Assets > $100B
22 Journal of Economic Perspectives
lead the
lead the average
capital ratio of banks in that state to decline. Second, we expect a
capital ratio of banks in that state to decline. Second, we expect a
compression effect
: the decline in capital ratios should be largest for those banks in the
: the decline in capital ratios should be largest for those banks in the
state that, prior to the shock, were operating with the highest capital ratios. Or said
state that, prior to the shock, were operating with the highest capital ratios. Or said
differently, we expect the regulatory shock to reduce the cross-sectional dispersion
differently, we expect the regulatory shock to reduce the cross-sectional dispersion
of capital ratios of banks in the given state.
of capital ratios of banks in the given state.
To implement our tests, we take data on the year that various state banking
To implement our tests, we take data on the year that various state banking
regulations were relaxed from Stiroh and Strahan (2003). We examine two types
regulations were relaxed from Stiroh and Strahan (2003). We examine two types
of deregulation: the easing of intrastate branching restrictions and the advent of
of deregulation: the easing of intrastate branching restrictions and the advent of
interstate banking. Prior to 1970, two-thirds of states had restrictions on intrastate
interstate banking. Prior to 1970, two-thirds of states had restrictions on intrastate
branching which were relaxed from 1975 to 1992. Between 1982 and 1993, 48 states
branching which were relaxed from 1975 to 1992. Between 1982 and 1993, 48 states
entered into regional or national agreements permitting interstate banking—i.e.,
entered into regional or national agreements permitting interstate banking—i.e.,
allowing out-of-state bank holding companies to own banks in their state. Given the
allowing out-of-state bank holding companies to own banks in their state. Given the
timing of deregulation, we focus on bank data (from bank Call Reports) over the
timing of deregulation, we focus on bank data (from bank Call Reports) over the
period from 1976 to 1994. Since our source of variation is at the state-year level, we
period from 1976 to 1994. Since our source of variation is at the state-year level, we
work with state-year aggregates. We estimate reduced-form regressions of the state-
work with state-year aggregates. We estimate reduced-form regressions of the state-
level equity-to-asset ratio on dummies that switch on in the year that a state relaxes
level equity-to-asset ratio on dummies that switch on in the year that a state relaxes
its regulations, along with state and year xed effects. We have two deregulatory
its regulations, along with state and year  xed effects. We have two deregulatory
dummies:
dummies: INTRASTATE
is based on the year that a state allows intrastate branching
is based on the year that a state allows intrastate branching
by mergers, while
by mergers, while INTERSTATE
is based on the year that a state enters a regional or
is based on the year that a state enters a regional or
national interstate banking agreement.
national interstate banking agreement.
Table 3 displays the results of these regressions where the dependent vari-
Table 3 displays the results of these regressions where the dependent vari-
able in the rst column is the mean equity-to-asset ratio in state
able in the  rst column is the mean equity-to-asset ratio in state s
in year
in year t
; in the
; in the
second column is the cross-sectional standard deviation of equity-to-assets; and in
second column is the cross-sectional standard deviation of equity-to-assets; and in
the remaining columns are the cross-sectional quantiles of the equity–asset ratio.
the remaining columns are the cross-sectional quantiles of the equity–asset ratio.
The results in the rst column imply that equity-to-assets falls by about 0.3 percentage
The results in the  rst column imply that equity-to-assets falls by about 0.3 percentage
points following intrastate branching and another 0.2 percentage points following
points following intrastate branching and another 0.2 percentage points following
interstate banking. Thus, equity-to-assets falls by roughly 0.5 percentage points for
interstate banking. Thus, equity-to-assets falls by roughly 0.5 percentage points for
the average state relaxing both restrictions. This decline can be compared to the
the average state relaxing both restrictions. This decline can be compared to the
typical cross-sectional standard deviation of 1.08 percentage points and is economi-
typical cross-sectional standard deviation of 1.08 percentage points and is economi-
cally meaningful considering that the average equity-to-assets ratio in our sample is
cally meaningful considering that the average equity-to-assets ratio in our sample is
just over 7 percent.
just over 7 percent.
The remaining columns in Table 3 show that, consistent with the notion of
The remaining columns in Table 3 show that, consistent with the notion of
a compression effect, the dispersion of capital ratios within a state falls following
a compression effect, the dispersion of capital ratios within a state falls following
deregulation, and capital ratios fall the most for those banks that were previously
deregulation, and capital ratios fall the most for those banks that were previously
in the upper tail of the distribution. This appears to have been particularly true
in the upper tail of the distribution. This appears to have been particularly true
following the advent of intrastate banking: the capital ratios of banks in the 75
following the advent of intrastate banking: the capital ratios of banks in the 75
th
th
and
and
90
90
th
th
percentiles of the distribution fall by 60 and 70 basis points, respectively, versus
percentiles of the distribution fall by 60 and 70 basis points, respectively, versus
only a 10 basis point change at the 10
only a 10 basis point change at the 10
th
th
and 25
and 25
th
th
percentiles.
percentiles.
In sum, the data support the hypothesis that when banks are faced with more
In sum, the data support the hypothesis that when banks are faced with more
intense competition, they gravitate towards both higher and more uniform levels
intense competition, they gravitate towards both higher and more uniform levels
of leverage. Such competitive effects combined with our earlier Modigliani–Miller-
of leverage. Such competitive effects combined with our earlier Modigliani–Miller-
based calibration results suggest one reason why tougher capital regulation of
based calibration results suggest one reason why tougher capital regulation of
nancial rms is appealing: it would seem to have the potential to reduce competition
nancial rms is appealing: it would seem to have the potential to reduce competition
A Macroprudential Approach to Financial Regulation 23
on a dimension that creates negative externalities and systemic risk, while at the
on a dimension that creates negative externalities and systemic risk, while at the
same time not raising loan rates by much. However, the complication is that these
same time not raising loan rates by much. However, the complication is that these
same competitive pressures also create powerful incentives to evade either the letter
same competitive pressures also create powerful incentives to evade either the letter
or the spirit of the rules. Thus, the most worrisome long-run byproduct of higher
or the spirit of the rules. Thus, the most worrisome long-run byproduct of higher
capital requirements will likely not be its effect on the cost of credit to borrowers, but
capital requirements will likely not be its effect on the cost of credit to borrowers, but
the pressure it creates for activity to migrate outside of the regulated banking sector.
the pressure it creates for activity to migrate outside of the regulated banking sector.
A Financial Reform Report Card
A Financial Reform Report Card
To conclude the paper, we brie y compare our proposals to policy reforms that
To conclude the paper, we brie y compare our proposals to policy reforms that
emerged in the second half of 2010. Our focus is primarily on the recommendations
emerged in the second half of 2010. Our focus is primarily on the recommendations
made by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision in September 2010 as part
made by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision in September 2010 as part
of the so-called “Basel III” process (see Basel Committee on Banking Supervision,
of the so-called “Basel III” process (see Basel Committee on Banking Supervision,
2010, for a summary). We will say less about the Wall Street Reform and Consumer
2010, for a summary). We will say less about the Wall Street Reform and Consumer
Protection Act—often called the Dodd–Frank legislation—that was signed into law
Protection Act—often called the Dodd–Frank legislation—that was signed into law
in July 2010. This is because our analysis has been centered on capital regulation
in July 2010. This is because our analysis has been centered on capital regulation
and closely related issues, the implementation of which has been taken up in more
and closely related issues, the implementation of which has been taken up in more
speci c numerical detail in Basel III; conversely, we have not attempted in this paper
speci c numerical detail in Basel III; conversely, we have not attempted in this paper
Table 3
Impact of Deregulation on Distribution of Equity-to-Assets within States
Dependent variable
Mean
Standard
deviation
10th
%tile
25th
%tile
50th
%tile
75th
%tile
90th
%tile
Regression 1: –0.288 –0.274 –0.099 –0.106 –0.193 –0.626 –0.682
INTRASTATE [–2.10] [–2.75] [–0.70] [–0.81] [–1.49] [–2.47] [–2.40]
Regression 2: –0.217 –0.133 0.037 –0.182 –0.278 –0.290 –0.349
INTERSTATE [–2.25] [–0.68] [0.31] [–1.46] [–2.68] [–1.96] [–1.73]
Regression 3: –0.281 –0.270 –0.100 –0.100 –0.183 –0.617 –0.671
INTRASTATE [–2.05] [–2.68] [–0.71] [–0.78] [–1.41] [–2.44] [–2.33]
INTERSTATE –0.203 –0.120 0.042 –0.177 –0.269 –0.261 –0.317
[–2.05] [–0.62] [0.34] [–1.43] [–2.62] [–1.69] [–1.47]
Sources: Based on an annual state-level panel from 1976–1994 assembled from bank Call Reports. The
deregulation dummies are based on the data in Table 1 of Stiroh and Strahan (2003).
Notes: The table shows regressions of equity-to-assets on dummies for deregulation. The INTRASTATE
dummies switch on beginning in the year when the state  rst permitted intrastate branching via mergers.
The INTERSTATE dummies switch on beginning in the year when the state entered a regional or national
interstate banking agreement. The dependent variables are alternately the asset-weighted average, standard
deviation, and quantiles of the equity-to-assets ratio within each state-year. The table reports coef cients
from 21 separate regressions (7 dependent variables each with 3 speci cations). All regressions include a
full set of state and year effects and have 969 observations (51 states × 19 years). t-statistics, in brackets, are
based on standard errors that are robust to clustering (i.e., serial correlation of residuals) at the state level.
24 Journal of Economic Perspectives
to speak to a number of the other central elements in Dodd–Frank, such as consumer
to speak to a number of the other central elements in Dodd–Frank, such as consumer
protection, regulation of over-the-counter derivatives, and resolution authority.
protection, regulation of over-the-counter derivatives, and resolution authority.
We have stressed the importance of requiring that nancial rms have both
We have stressed the importance of requiring that  nancial rms have both
more capital, and, crucially, higher-quality capital. On this score, the Basel III
more capital, and, crucially, higher-quality capital. On this score, the Basel III
recommendations look quite good. They would raise the minimum common equity
recommendations look quite good. They would raise the minimum common equity
requirement from 2 percent of risk-weighted assets to 7 percent (this is inclusive of
requirement from 2 percent of risk-weighted assets to 7 percent (this is inclusive of
a “capital conservation buffer”). While we have argued for a higher number, this is a
a “capital conservation buffer”). While we have argued for a higher number, this is a
signi cant step in the right direction. Moreover, systemically important institutions
signi cant step in the right direction. Moreover, systemically important institutions
will be required to have an additional, as-yet-undetermined increment in terms of
will be required to have an additional, as-yet-undetermined increment in terms of
equity capital, which, if it turns out to be material, would be further good news.
equity capital, which, if it turns out to be material, would be further good news.
The major shortcoming on the equity capital front is its very slow phase-in; the
The major shortcoming on the equity capital front is its very slow phase-in; the
new requirements do not become fully effective until January 2019. The motivation
new requirements do not become fully effective until January 2019. The motivation
for this slow phase-in is the concern that if banks are asked to comply with the higher
for this slow phase-in is the concern that if banks are asked to comply with the higher
ratios in a more compressed timeframe, they will do so by shrinking their balance
ratios in a more compressed timeframe, they will do so by shrinking their balance
sheets rather than by raising new external equity capital, thereby causing a further
sheets rather than by raising new external equity capital, thereby causing a further
credit crunch. While we agree that this worry might be legitimate if the phase-in is
credit crunch. While we agree that this worry might be legitimate if the phase-in is
truncated and no other offsetting steps are taken, our above analysis suggests an
truncated and no other offsetting steps are taken, our above analysis suggests an
obvious alternative: during the phase-in period, regulators should push those banks
obvious alternative: during the phase-in period, regulators should push those banks
that are shy of the new capital standards to
that are shy of the new capital standards to raise new dollars of equity
, rather than giving
, rather than giving
them the option to adjust via asset shrinkage. The U.S. stress tests conducted in 2009
them the option to adjust via asset shrinkage. The U.S. stress tests conducted in 2009
showed that this approach can work, and if it were applied again, the phase-in period
showed that this approach can work, and if it were applied again, the phase-in period
could be made much shorter with little adverse impact on credit supply.
could be made much shorter with little adverse impact on credit supply.
We also discussed the usefulness of time-varying capital requirements. Here the
We also discussed the usefulness of time-varying capital requirements. Here the
Basel Committee proposes an additional
Basel Committee proposes an additional countercyclical buffer
that will range between
that will range between
0 and 2.5 percent, to be implemented on a country-by-country basis. As the report
0 and 2.5 percent, to be implemented on a country-by-country basis. As the report
states: “The purpose of the countercyclical buffer is to achieve the broader macro
states: “The purpose of the countercyclical buffer is to achieve the broader macro
prudential goal of protecting the banking sector in periods of excess aggregate
prudential goal of protecting the banking sector in periods of excess aggregate
credit growth. For any given country, this buffer will only be in effect when there is
credit growth. For any given country, this buffer will only be in effect when there is
excess credit growth that is resulting in a system wide build up of risk.” This too is a
excess credit growth that is resulting in a system wide build up of risk.” This too is a
step in the right direction, though we worry that the wording would seem to require
step in the right direction, though we worry that the wording would seem to require
an af rmative  nding of “excess credit growth” for the requirement to kick in; one
an af rmative  nding of “excess credit growth” for the requirement to kick in; one
can imagine that it will be politically challenging for regulators to make this case
can imagine that it will be politically challenging for regulators to make this case
when they ought to.
when they ought to.
Other elements of the reform package remain less well developed. For example,
Other elements of the reform package remain less well developed. For example,
on the topic of debt maturity, the Basel Committee introduces the concept of a
on the topic of debt maturity, the Basel Committee introduces the concept of a
“net stable funding ratio” test—a requirement that nancial rms’ capital structures
“net stable funding ratio” test—a requirement that  nancial rms’ capital structures
have a certain amount of long-term funding, which would encompass both equity
have a certain amount of long-term funding, which would encompass both equity
and debt with a maturity of greater than one year. However, the details regarding
and debt with a maturity of greater than one year. However, the details regarding
the design and calibration of this rule remain to be worked out, with an “observa-
the design and calibration of this rule remain to be worked out, with an “observa-
tion period” to begin in 2012 and the introduction of the standard itself put off
tion period” to begin in 2012 and the introduction of the standard itself put off
until 2018.
until 2018.
Similarly, while the Basel Committee continues to study various forms of contin-
Similarly, while the Basel Committee continues to study various forms of contin-
gent capital, it has not yet reached any nal conclusions; a review is scheduled to
gent capital, it has not yet reached any  nal conclusions; a review is scheduled to
Samuel G. Hanson, Anil K Kashyap, and Jeremy C. Stein 25
be completed in mid 2011. Interestingly, however, Swiss banking regulators have
be completed in mid 2011. Interestingly, however, Swiss banking regulators have
chosen to move forward on their own on this front. The Final Report of the Swiss
chosen to move forward on their own on this front. The Final Report of the Swiss
Commission of Experts proposed that the two big Swiss banks—UBS and Credit
Commission of Experts proposed that the two big Swiss banks—UBS and Credit
Suisse—be required to have 19 percent total capital by 2019. Of this, 10 percent
Suisse—be required to have 19 percent total capital by 2019. Of this, 10 percent
would have to be in common equity (a higher standard than the 7 percent under
would have to be in common equity (a higher standard than the 7 percent under
Basel III) while the remaining 9 percent could, at the bank’s discretion, take the
Basel III) while the remaining 9 percent could, at the bank’s discretion, take the
form of contingent convertibles that would convert when the ratio of equity to assets
form of contingent convertibles that would convert when the ratio of equity to assets
hit a predetermined trigger value (Morgan Stanley Research, 2010). This “opting”
hit a predetermined trigger value (Morgan Stanley Research, 2010). This “opting”
approach to contingent capital is, both qualitatively and quantitatively, closely in
approach to contingent capital is, both qualitatively and quantitatively, closely in
line with what we described above.
line with what we described above.
Finally, perhaps the most glaring weak spot in nancial reform thus far—one
Finally, perhaps the most glaring weak spot in  nancial reform thus far—one
that cuts across both the Dodd–Frank legislation and the Basel III process—is the
that cuts across both the Dodd–Frank legislation and the Basel III process—is the
failure to fully come to grips with the shadow banking system. As we have emphasized,
failure to fully come to grips with the shadow banking system. As we have emphasized,
if one takes a macroprudential view, the overarching goal of nancial regulation
if one takes a macroprudential view, the overarching goal of  nancial regulation
must go beyond protecting insured depositories and even beyond dealing with the
must go beyond protecting insured depositories and even beyond dealing with the
problems created by “too-big-to-fail” nonbank intermediaries. Instead, the task is to
problems created by “too-big-to-fail” nonbank intermediaries. Instead, the task is to
mitigate the re-sales and credit-crunch effects that can arise as a consequence of
mitigate the  re-sales and credit-crunch effects that can arise as a consequence of
excessive short-term debt
excessive short-term debt anywhere in the  nancial system
.
.
While higher capital and liquidity requirements on banks will no doubt help to
While higher capital and liquidity requirements on banks will no doubt help to
insulate banks from the consequences of large shocks, the danger is that, given the
insulate banks from the consequences of large shocks, the danger is that, given the
intensity of competition in nancial services, they will also drive a larger share of
intensity of competition in  nancial services, they will also drive a larger share of
intermediation into the shadow banking realm. For example, perhaps an increasing
intermediation into the shadow banking realm. For example, perhaps an increasing
fraction of corporate and consumer loans will be securitized and in their securitized
fraction of corporate and consumer loans will be securitized and in their securitized
form will end up being held by a variety of highly leveraged investors (say hedge
form will end up being held by a variety of highly leveraged investors (say hedge
funds) who are not subject to the usual bank-oriented capital regulation. If so,
funds) who are not subject to the usual bank-oriented capital regulation. If so,
the individual regulated banks may be safer than they were before, but the overall
the individual regulated banks may be safer than they were before, but the overall
system of credit creation may not.
system of credit creation may not.
To safeguard the system as a whole, attention must be paid to not tilting the
To safeguard the system as a whole, attention must be paid to not tilting the
playing eld in a way that generates damaging unintended consequences. Admit-
playing  eld in a way that generates damaging unintended consequences. Admit-
tedly, regulating the shadow banking sector and the other parts of the nancial
tedly, regulating the shadow banking sector and the other parts of the  nancial
system consistently is a complex task, and one that will require a variety of speci c
system consistently is a complex task, and one that will require a variety of speci c
tools. As one concrete rst step, we reiterate that it would be a good idea to establish
tools. As one concrete  rst step, we reiterate that it would be a good idea to establish
regulatory minimum haircut requirements on asset-backed securities, so that no
regulatory minimum haircut requirements on asset-backed securities, so that no
investor who takes a position in credit assets is able to evade constraints on short-
investor who takes a position in credit assets is able to evade constraints on short-
term leverage.
term leverage.
This discussion raises a nal question about how such regulation might be
This discussion raises a  nal question about how such regulation might be
implemented. In the United States and in Europe, macroprudential oversight has
implemented. In the United States and in Europe, macroprudential oversight has
been delegated to large councils: the Financial Stability Oversight Committee and
been delegated to large councils: the Financial Stability Oversight Committee and
the European System Risk Board, respectively. Membership of both groups consists
the European System Risk Board, respectively. Membership of both groups consists
of the heads of many regulatory organizations. Whether either council can function
of the heads of many regulatory organizations. Whether either council can function
effectively and avoid turf wars is an open question. But these committees will be
effectively and avoid turf wars is an open question. But these committees will be
pivotal in determining whether existing weaknesses in the regulatory system—such
pivotal in determining whether existing weaknesses in the regulatory system—such
as those having to do with the shadow banking sector—can be addressed sensibly.
as those having to do with the shadow banking sector—can be addressed sensibly.
26 Journal of Economic Perspectives
We are grateful for helpful comments from Charles Goodhart, Arvind Krishnamurthy, Andrew
Metrick, Victoria Saporta, Hyun Shin, Andrei Shleifer, René Stulz, Lawrence Summers, Paul
Tucker, seminar participants at numerous institutions, and JEP editors David Autor, Chad
Jones, and Timothy Taylor. Kashyap thanks the Initiative on Global Markets and the Center
for Research on Securities Prices for research support on this project.
References
Bank of England. 2009. “The Role of Macro-
prudential Policy: A Discussion Paper.” November.
http://www.bankofengland.co.uk/publications
/other/ nancialstability/roleofmacroprudential
policy091121.pdf.
Basel Committee on Banking Supervision. 2010.
“The Basel Committee’s Response to the Financial
Crisis: Report to the G20.” October.
http://www
.bis.org/publ/bcbs179.pdf.
Berger, Allen N., Richard J. Herring, and
Giorgio P. Szego. 1995. “The Role of Capital in
Financial Institutions.” Journal of Banking and
Finance, 19(3–4): 393–430.
Berger, Allen N., Nathan H. Miller, Mitchell A.
Petersen, Raghuram Rajan, and Jeremy C. Stein.
2005. “Does Function Follow Organizational Form?
Evidence from the Lending Practices of Large and
Small Banks.”
Journal of Financial Economics, 76(2):
237–69.
Bernanke, Ben S. 2008. “Reducing Systemic
Risk.” Speech at the Federal Reserve Bank of
Kansas City’s Annual Economic Symposium,
Jackson Hole, Wyoming, August 22, 2008.
Borio, Claudio. 2003. “Towards a Macropru-
dential Framework for Financial Supervision and
Regulation?” BIS Working Paper 128.
Borio, Claudio, Craig Fur ne, and Phillip
Lowe. 2001. “Procyclicality of the Financial System
and Financial Stability: Issues and Policy Options.”
In Marrying the Macro- and Micro-Prudential Dimen-
sions of Financial Stability, BIS Papers 1, Bank for
International Settlements, pp. 1–57. http://www
.bis.org/publ/bppdf/bispap01.htm.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System. 1943. Banking and Monetary Statistics,
1919–1941. Washington: Publications Services of
the Board of Governors. Washington, DC.
Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve
System. 1959. All Bank Statistics, United States,
1896–1955. Washington: Publications Services of
the Board of Governors. Washington, DC.
Brunnermeier, Markus, Andrew Crockett,
Charles Goodhart, Avinash D. Persaud, and Hyun
Shin. 2009. “The Fundamental Principles of Finan-
cial Regulation.” Geneva Reports on the World
Economy 11.
Brunnermeier, Markus K., and Lasse H.
Pedersen. 2009. “Market Liquidity and Funding
Liquidity.” Review of Financial Studies, 22(6):
2201–38.
Bryant, John. 1980. “A Model of Reserves, Bank
Runs, and Deposit Insurance.” Journal of Banking
and Finance, 4(4): 335–44.
Caballero, Ricardo, and Alp Simsek. 2010. “Fire
Sales in a Model of Complexity.” NBER Working
Paper 15479.
Covitz, Daniel, Nellie Liang, and Gustavo
Suarez. 2009. “The Anatomy of a Financial Crisis:
The Evolution of Panic-Driven Runs in the Asset-
Backed Commercial Paper Market.” Finance and
Economics Discussion Series Working Paper 2009-
36, Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve.
Crockett, Andrew. 2000, “Marrying the Micro-
and Macroprudential Dimensions of Financial
Stability.” BIS Speeches, September 21.
Diamond, Douglas W., and Philip Dybvig. 1983.
A Macroprudential Approach to Financial Regulation 27
“Bank Runs, Deposit Insurance and Liquidity.”
Journal of Political Economy, 91(3): 401–419.
Diamond, Douglas W., and Raghuram G. Rajan.
2009. “Fear of Fire Sales and the Credit Freeze.”
NBER Working Paper 14925.
Duf e, Darrell. 2010. How Big Banks Fail and
What To Do About It. Princeton University Press.
Flannery, Mark J. 2005 “No Pain, No Gain?
Effecting Market Discipline via ‘Reverse Convert-
ible Debentures.’” In Capital Adequacy beyond Basel:
Banking, Securities, and Insurance, 171–97. Oxford
University Press.
French, Kenneth R., Martin N. Baily, John
Y. Campbell, John H. Cochrane, Douglas W.
Diamond, Darrell Duf e, Anil K Kashyap, Frederic
S. Mishkin, Raghuram G. Rajan, David S. Scharf-
stein, Robert J. Shiller, Hyun Song Shin, Matthew
J. Slaughter, Jeremy C. Stein, and René M. Stulz.
2010. The Squam Lake Report: Fixing the Financial
System. Princeton University Press.
Geanakoplos, John. 2010. “The Leverage Cycle.”
Cowles Foundation Discussion Paper 1715R.
Geanakoplos, John, and Heraklis Pole-
marchakis. 1986. “Existence, Regularity and
Constrained Suboptimality of Competitive Alloca-
tions When the Asset Market Is Incomplete.”
In Essays in Honor of Kenneth Arrow, Vol 3. ed. W.
Heller, R. Starr, and D. Starrett, 65–95. Cambridge
University Press.
Gorton, Gary B. 2010. Slapped by the Invisible
Hand: The Panic of 2007. Oxford University Press.
Gorton, Gary B., and Andrew Metrick. 2010.
“Securitized Banking and the Run on Repo.” Yale
ICF Working Paper 09-14.
Hanson, Samuel, and Adi Sunderam. 2010. “Are
There Too Many Safe Securities? Securitization
and the Incentives for Information Production.”
http://www.people.fas.harvard.edu/~sunderam
/papers/sunderam_JMP.pdf.
Hart, Oliver, and Luigi Zingales. 2010. “A
New Capital Regulation for Large Financial
Institutions.” http://faculty.chicagobooth.
edu/luigi.zingales/papers/A_New_Capital
_Regulation_ALER_version.pdf.
Hirtle, Beverly, Til Schuermann, and Kevin
Stiroh. 2009. “Macroprudential Supervision of
Financial Institutions: Lessons from the SCAP.”
Federal Reserve Bank of New York Staff Report 409.
International Monetary Fund. 2010. Global
Financial Stability Report. April. Washington, DC:
International Monetary Fund.
Ivashina, Victoria, and David Scharfstein. 2010.
“Bank Lending During the Financial Crisis of
2008.” Journal of Financial Economics, 97(3): 319–38.
Kashyap, Anil K, Richard Berner, and Charles A.
E. Goodhart. Forthcoming. “The Macroprudential
Toolkit.” IMF Economic Review.
Kashyap, Anil K, Raghuram Rajan, and Jeremy
C. Stein. 2008. “Rethinking Capital Regulation.” In
Maintaining Stability in a Changing Financial System,
431–71. Federal Reserve Bank of Kansas City.
Kashyap, Anil K, and Jeremy C. Stein. 2004.
“Cyclical Implications of the Basel-II Capital Stan-
dards.” Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Economic
Perspectives, vol. 28, Q1, pp. 18–31.
Kashyap, Anil K, Jeremy C. Stein, and Samuel
Hanson. 2010. “An Analysis of the Impact of
‘Substantially Heightened’ Capital Requirements
on Large Financial Institutions.” http://faculty
.chicagobooth.edu/anil.kashyap/research
/an_analysis_of_the_impact_of_substantially
_heightened.pdf.
Krishnamurthy, Arvind, and Annette Vissing-
Jorgensen. 2010. “The Aggregate Demand
for Treasury Debt.” http://www.kellogg
.northwestern.edu/faculty/vissing/htm/demand
treas_may122010_jperevision.pdf.
McDonald, Robert L. 2010. “Contingent
Capital with a Dual Price Trigger.” http://papers
.ssrn.com/sol3/papers.cfm?abstract_id=1553430.
Modigliani, Franco, and Merton H. Miller. 1958.
“The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the
Theory of Investment.” American Economic Review,
48(3): 261–97.
Morgan Stanley Research. 2010. “European
Banks: €49 Billion of Swiss CoCos.” October 4.
Myers, Stewart C. 1977. “Determinants
of Corporate Borrowing.” Journal of Financial
Economics, 5(2): 147–75.
Myers, Stewart C., and Nicolas Majluf. 1984.
“Corporate Financing and Investment Decisions
When Firms Have Information That Investors Do
Not Have.” Journal of Financial Economics, 13(2):
187–222.
Petersen, Mitchell, and Raghuram Rajan. 1994.
“The Bene ts of Lending Relationships: Evidence
from Small Business Data.” Journal of Finance,
49(1): 3–37.
Petersen, Mitchell, and Raghuram Rajan.
1995. “The Effect of Credit Market Competition
on Lending Relationships.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 110(2): 407–44.
Rajan, Raghuram. 1992. “Insiders and
Outsiders: The Choice between Relationship
and Arms-Length Debt.” Journal of Finance, 47(4):
1367–1400.
Shin, Hyun Song. 2009. “Re ections on
Northern Rock: The Bank Run that Heralded
the Global Financial Crisis.” Journal of Economic
Perspectives, 23(1), 101–119.
Shleifer, Andrei, and Robert W. Vishny. 2010.
“Unstable Banking.” Journal of Financial Economics,
28 Journal of Economic Perspectives
97(3): 306–18.
Stein, Jeremy C. 2010a. “Monetary Policy
as Financial-Stability Regulation.” http://www
.economics.harvard.edu/faculty/stein/files
/MonetaryPolicyAsRegulation-8-2010.pdf.
Stein, Jeremy C. 2010b. “Securitization, Shadow
Banking, and Financial Fragility.” Daedalus, 139(4):
41–51.
Stiroh, Kevin J., and Philip E. Strahan. 2003.
“Competitive Dynamics of Deregulation: Evidence
from U.S. Banking.” Journal of Money, Credit, and
Banking, 35(5): 801–28.
Tucker, Paul. 2010. “Shadow Banking, Financ-
ing Markets and Financial Stability.” Speech at a
Bernie Gerald Cantor (BGC) Partners Seminar,
London, January, 21, 2010.