DAVID MERRIMAN
POLICY FOCUS REPORT LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
ISBN 978–1–55844–377–8 (paper)
Policy Focus Report/Code PF050
ISBN 978–1–55844–378–5 (PDF)
IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING (TIF) FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
DAVID MERRIMAN
ISBN 978-1-55844-377-8
Improving Tax Increment Financing (TIF)
for Economic Development
One of the main responsibilities of local government is to promote economic activity for the benefit of all stakeholders,
including residents and businesses. Tax increment financing (TIF) is one tool that cities can use to support economic
development in a designated area by earmarking property tax revenues from anticipated increases in assessed
property values resulting from investment in that district. Virtually every state allows some form of TIF, which requires
cooperation between government and the private sector.
Yet, the fundamental attributes of TIF are still poorly understood, and its effectiveness is disputed. Many states
do little to track or evaluate the use of TIF. Recent findings show that TIF does little to deliver economic growth and
sometimes simply relocates economic activity that would have occurred elsewhere without TIF. Empirical studies
suggest that communities should use TIF cautiously to avoid diverting increased property tax revenues from overlying
governments, obscuring government financial records, and facilitating unproductive fiscal competition between
neighboring jurisdictions.
Written by an expert and educator in public finance, business taxation, and urban economic development, this report
presents data about TIF usage, explains how it is intended to work, notes its conceptual strengths and limitations,
reviews academic evaluations of its use, and offers the following recommendations for improving its design.
States should track and monitor TIF use.
States should revise statutes to allow counties,
school districts, and other overlying local govern-
ments to opt out of contributing resources to TIF
districts.
State legislators should review their “but for”
TIF requirements to determine whether they
are effective.
Local governments should provide extensive, easily
accessible information about TIF use, revenues, and
expenditures.
Researchers should study, document, and explain the
different outcomes resulting from TIF use in various
geographic areas.
Improving Tax Increment Financing (TIF)
for Economic Development
Front Cover: Founded in 2002, the Cortex Innovation District
in St. Louis is the Midwest’s innovation hub of development,
bioscience and technology research, and commercialization
for start-up programs and established companies in the area.
Top: An intersection in the Cortex District after the first stage of
development. Photo: Cortex Innovation Community.
Bottom: This view of the same St. Louis intersection in 2016 shows
the completed Commons during The Murmuration Festival, a three-
day event hosted by Cortex so the public could enjoy the site and
explore the intersection of local art, music, science, and technology.
Photo: Cortex Innovation Community. Photograph by Louis Kwok.
Back Cover: The Pritzker Pavilion, designed by renowned architect
Frank Gehry, features large in Chicagos Millennium Park, which was
partially funded by TIF. Photo: Serge Melki/Flickr CC BY 2.0.
Ordering Information
To download a free copy of this
report or to order copies, visit
www.lincolninst.edu and search
by author or title. For additional
information on discounted prices
for bookstores, multiple-copy
orders, and shipping and handling
costs, send your inquiry to
lincolnorders@pssc.com.
EDITOR & PROJECT MANAGER
Emily McKeigue
COPY EDITOR
Allison Bernstein
DESIGN & PRODUCTION
Studio Rainwater
PRINTING
Recycled Paper Printing
113 Brattle Street, Cambridge, MA
02138-3400, USA
P (617) 661-3016 or (800) 526-3873
F (617) 661-7235 or (800) 526-3944
help
@lincolninst.edu
lincolninst.edu
Recycled paper. Printed using
soy-based inks.
ABOUT THIS REPORT
This report explains how tax increment financing (TIF)
districts work, illustrates TIF use with case studies from
around the country, discusses the rationales for using TIF,
describes TIF’s potential benefits and pitfalls, and reviews
a large body of academic work that evaluates TIF’s effects
on economic development. The author also examines
additional academic literature about the impact of TIF on
school districts and other potential unintended side effects.
The report concludes that, although results are mixed, TIF
often fails to meet its primary goal to increase real estate
development and other economic growth. Based on these
findings, the report offers recommendations to make TIF
districts more successful, equitable, and efficient. David
Merriman is an expert in state and local public finance,
business taxation, and urban economic development. He
teaches and performs research in the Department of Public
Administration and the Institute of Government and Public
Affairs at the University of Illinois at Chicago. His research
has been published in many peer review journals, and he is
frequently quoted in local and national news media.
113 Brattle Street, Cambridge, MA
02138-3400, USA
P (617) 661-3016 or (800) 526-3873
F (617) 661-7235 or (800) 526-3944
help
@lincolninst.edu
lincolninst.edu
Copyright © 2018 Lincoln Institute of Land Policy
All rights reserved.
POLICY FOCUS REPORT SERIES
The policy focus report series is published by the
Lincoln Institute of Land Policy to address timely public
policy issues relating to land use, land markets, and
property taxation. Each report is designed to bridge
the gap between theory and practice by combining
research findings, case studies, and contributions from
scholars in a variety of academic disciplines, and from
professional practitioners, local officials, and citizens in
diverse communities.
ISBN 978-1-55844-377-8 (paper)
Policy Focus Report/Code: PF050
ISBN 978-1-55844-378-5 (PDF)
ABOUT THE LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
www.lincolninst.edu
The Lincoln Institute of Land Policy seeks to improve quality of life through
the effective use, taxation, and stewardship of land. A nonprofit, private
operating foundation whose origins date to 1946, the Lincoln Institute
researches and recommends creative approaches to land as a solution to
economic, social, and environmental challenges. Through education, train-
ing, publications, and events, we integrate theory and practice to inform
public policy decisions worldwide. With locations in Cambridge, Mas-
sachusetts; Washington, DC; Phoenix; and Beijing, we organize our work
in seven major areas: Planning and Urban Form, Valuation and Taxation,
International and Institute-Wide Initiatives, Latin America and the Carib-
bean, Peoples Republic of China, the Babbitt Center for Land and Water
Policy, and the Center for Community Investment.
3 Executive Summary
5 Chapter 1 Introduction
6 What Is Tax Increment Financing (TIF)?
6 What Are TIF Districts and How Do They Work?
9 How Does a TIF District Work in Practice?
13 Chapter 2 Potential Benefits and Pitfalls
14 What Are the Potential Benefits of TIF?
15 What Are the Potential Pitfalls of TIF?
17 Chapter 3 Case Studies
18 Case Study 1: Atlanta BeltLine Tax Allocation
District, Georgia
20 Case Study 2: Jefferson County, Montana
22 Case Study 3: St. Louis, Missouri
24 Chapter 4 Use and Implementation
25 Where Has TIF Been Used?
32 How Has TIF Been Used?
35 Chapter 5 Transparency: Intensive TIF Use in Chicago
36 Background
38 Reform Efforts
41 Chapter 6 TIF Reversal: Californias Story
42 History
42 Limitations
43 Results
Contents
3
5
13
17
44 Chapter 7 Efficacy in Economic Development
45 Assessing TIF’s Successes and Failures
47 Effects of TIF Adoption on Economic Activity
53 Effects of TIF Adoption on School Finance
53 Other Effects of TIF Adoption
56 Chapter 8 Conclusion
57 Findings
58 Recommendations
59 Appendix
62 References
67 Acknowledgments
68 About the Author
24
35
41
44
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 3
Executive Summary
Crowds in Chicago celebrate the
opening of the Bloomingdale Trail
and Park, which was partially funded
through TIF. Photo: Charles Carper/
Flickr CC BY 2.0.
Promoting economic activity is a key function of local
government and requires cooperation between the govern-
ment and the private sector. Tax increment financing (TIF) is
one tool that cities can use to support economic development
in a designated area by earmarking property tax revenues from
anticipated increases in assessed property values resulting
from investment in that district. TIF expenditures are often debt
financed in anticipation of these future tax revenues.
4 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Although a number of states have used TIF for more
than half a century, TIF is poorly understood and its
effectiveness is disputed. This report presents basic
data about TIF usage, explains how it is intended to
work, notes its conceptual strengths and limitations,
reviews academic evaluations of its use, and suggests
methods for improving its design.
Today, TIF is legal and employed widely in every state
except Arizona, with heavy use in the Midwest. Yet,
many states do little to track or evaluate the use of
TIF. Academic research suggests that local govern-
ments enact TIF in part to capture growth that was
already occurring and in part to stimulate further eco-
nomic development. Studies also indicate that TIF’s
impact on economic activity is mixed: Many recent
findings show that TIF does little to deliver economic
growth and sometimes simply relocates economic
activity that would have occurred elsewhere without
TIF. Empirical studies of other TIF-related effects,
including its impact on school finance, land uses, and
budgeting, suggest that communities should use it
cautiously to avoid unintended consequences, such
as diverting increased property tax revenues from
counties, school districts, and other overlying govern-
ments; obscuring government financial records; and
facilitating unproductive fiscal competition between
neighboring jurisdictions.
This report lays out the following recommendations
to address these concerns and help state and local
governments improve TIF’s usefulness.
1. States should track and monitor TIF use.
Basic monitoring helps states evaluate the use of
TIF and helps state legislators better understand
whether TIF regulations are achieving their goals.
2. States should revise statutes to allow coun-
ties, school districts, and other overlying
local governments to opt out of contributing
resources to TIF districts. This measure would
diminish or eliminate the incentive for local
governments to use TIF as a device to capture
revenues that otherwise would have gone to
overlying governments.
3. State legislators should review their “but for”
TIF requirements to determine whether they
are effective. Prior to the creation of a TIF
district, some states require proof that the
planned development would not occur “but
for” the tax increment financing. An effective
“but for” clause can prevent communities
from using TIF when other tools might be more
helpful and transparent.
4. Local governments should provide extensive,
easily accessible information about TIF use,
revenues, and expenditures. This information
would enable local elected officials to monitor
and regulate the application of TIF, shortening
the duration of TIF arrangements, for example,
or making other adjustments to the terms of
use as needed.
5. Researchers should study, document, and
explain the different outcomes resulting from
TIF use in various geographic areas. To date,
academic studies of TIF document mixed out-
comes but do not clearly identify the factors
that explain this variation.
The basic design of TIF has significant virtues, but
decades of experience and research from around
the United States show that often TIF is flawed in
practice. This report argues that, if used properly,
TIF can be an important tool to nurture economic
development in the public interest.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 5
CHAPTER 1
Introduction
A community’s economic growth and the well-being of its
residents are inextricably linked. Indeed, an areas prosperity
and its citizens quality of life of depend in no small part on
the creation and maintenance of jobs that are both materi-
ally and emotionally rewarding. A communitys success also
requires regularly revitalized commercial activity; the main-
tenance and renewal of infrastructure; and the provision
of public goods, buildings, and services like police, schools,
hospitals, and public recreation areas.
Minnesotas state legislature specifies
the requirements for establishing a
TIF district. Photo: Minnesota
Historical Society.
6 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
In the United States, a community’s economic growth
is an important government function that requires
coordination with the private sector. Motivated primarily
by economic profit, the private sector is well positioned
to act rapidly and efficiently when customers clearly
desire goods or services. Sometimes, private-sector
investments that may otherwise be viable can face sig-
nificant impediments. These obstacles might be simple
physical incompatibilities, like viaducts that are too
low to allow modern truck traffic or complicated social
problems, such as a workforce plagued by inadequate
training and high crime rates. When such impediments
arise, they can often be remediated by a combination of
private-sector and governmental activity.
How can these sectors work together? While the private
sector pursues profit, government aims to provide its
target population with vital goods and services that are
balanced against the costs imposed on that populace,
generally as taxes and fees. Sometimes for-profit and
government organizations receive assistance from
private nonprofits dedicated to delivering particular
goods and services, such as healthcare or affordable
housing, to the target population. In addition, the
government can use certain powers, including laws,
regulations, and taxes, to compel private-sector actions.
But the system operates best when government and
private-sector actors work in harmony to achieve
compatible goals by using their own tools—and TIF
can provide a framework for that cooperation.
What Is Tax Increment
Financing (TIF)?
Tax increment financing is an economic development
method designed to coordinate the actions of govern-
ment and the for-profit sector. TIF funds economic
development activities in a designated area by earmark-
ing the anticipated property tax revenue increases—
often called the “increment”—that will result if the TIF
investment stimulates new development and real
estate appreciation. Core elements of TIF include:
a designated district with narrowly defined
geographic boundaries;
a defined and limited operation period;
expenditures that encourage economic
development; and
real estate appreciation that generates new
property tax revenues.
As implemented in most states, TIF allows city govern-
ments to divert revenues of overlying governments—such
as counties, school districts, or other special districts
that share responsibility for providing public services—
to fund economic development activities. The rationale
is that diverted revenues are produced by the same
economic development that they fund—so these reve-
nues would not exist “but for” the TIF that enabled that
development. Therefore, in theory, there is no loss to the
overlying governments. Also, since revenues accrue only
with appreciation, developers receive no subsidy unless
they create economic development.
What Are TIF Districts and
How Do They Work?
The basic principles of TIF operation are consistent and
widespread: State legislation sets the conditions under
which TIF districts may be established and, subject to
state oversight, grants cities the right to operate TIFs.
These city governments typically pass an ordinance that
creates the TIF district and specifies the district’s goals,
allowed expenditures, and terms of operation.
The TIF district’s revenues are then derived from property
taxes on the appreciation, development, and redevel-
opment of real estate within its borders. In general, that
revenue comes from property taxes that would otherwise
accrue for both the creating government and overlying
governments that levy property taxes on parcels within
the TIF district. Tax increment financing allows those
revenues to accrue for the benefit of the district itself.
Figure 1 illustrates this process. The curve for assessed
value without TIF shows the hypothetical value of par-
cels in the TIF district in the absence of the TIF district.
As depicted, the value of the parcels would have grown
from about $100 to almost $200 million between 2000
and 2020, even if a TIF district had not been estab-
lished. The curve for assessed value with TIF depicts
the hypothetical value of the parcels if the TIF district
The basic principles of TIF operation
are consistent and widespread: State
legislation sets the conditions under
which TIF districts may be established
and, subject to state oversight, grants
cities the right to operate TIFs.
Figure 1
Hypothetical Example of Assessed
Value With and Without TIF
Pre-TIF
BASE VALUE
Assessed value with TIF
450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
0
Assessed Value (in millions $)
with TIF
without TIF
Year
Base value
Increment caused by TIF
Base value
Pre-TIF
Assessed value without TIF
Assessed value pre-TIF
was created beginning in 2006. In this scenario, real
estate values grow more rapidly and, by the end of the
period, are valued at more than $400 million rather
than nearly $200 million. The base value of the TIF dis-
trict is the value of the real estate in the district at the
time the TIF district was established (approximately
$130 million, in this example).
The TIF district’s tax base (increment) is the difference
between the assessed value with TIF and the base
value when the TIF district was created. The tax rate
on the TIF tax base (not shown in the figure) is the sum
of the tax rates of all overlying governments, such as
counties, school districts, and other special districts.
A given tax rate generates less revenue for overlying
governments with a TIF in place than it would in the
absence of the TIF—unless the value of real estate
parcels in the TIF district would not have grown at all
without the TIF district designation. In figure 1, the
distance between the assessed value without TIF
curve and the base value represents the tax base lost
to overlying governments through the formation of the
TIF district.
Pre-TIF
BASE VALUE
Assessed value with TIF
450
400
350
300
250
200
150
100
50
2000 2005 2010 2015 2020
0
Assessed Value (in millions $)
with TIF
without TIF
Year
Base value
Increment caused by TIF
Base value
Pre-TIF
Assessed value without TIF
Assessed value pre-TIF
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 7
8 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Often, TIF financing involves other sources
of revenue, including state or federal
matching funds or, in some cases, other
tax revenues.
The precise way in which TIF districts are formed and
operate varies from state to state and from case to
case. There is no simple typology to classify TIF dis-
tricts, but for the purposes of this report, they can be
divided based on the statutory conditions necessary for
their formation and the sources and uses of financing.
State-enabling legislation sometimes allows for sepa-
rate qualifying conditions for several different types of
TIF districts. For example, Minnesotas legislation allows
for six district types: economic development, housing,
redevelopment, renewal and renovation, soil condition,
and hazardous waste substance subdivisions (Minne-
sota House of Representatives 2017). Illinois allows the
use of TIF to remediate blight, to conserve areas with
many structures older than 35 years, and to promote
industrial parks in areas of high unemployment (Illinois
Tax Increment Redevelopment Act 2014).
Once a TIF district is formed, its finances can proceed
along a number of different paths as real estate in the
area appreciates and it begins to receive property tax
revenues. Sometimes, new private investments result
from the simple announcement that a TIF district has
been formed with the promise of future economic
development revenue. Thus, property values may grow
even prior to any substantial public investment. In this
case, the TIF district may be funded on a pay-as-you-go
basis: As appreciation creates TIF property tax reve-
nues, local governments can use the funds to improve
infrastructure or to compensate private developers for
allowable costs, such as building and site rehabilitation
or repair, or professional services, such as architectural
or engineering consultation.
In other cases, the mere announcement of a TIF district
is insufficient to stir private investment, meaning that
public spending may have to occur first. In this case,
a TIF development plan, together with the assurance
of a dedicated revenue source from real estate appre-
ciation, can be sufficient to attract financing for the
TIF. Typically, state legislation will explicitly allow local
governments to pledge proceeds from TIF districts as
a source of bond finance. If the TIF district development
plan is compelling, the municipality may even be able
to create a bond-financed TIF by selling bonds with the
promise that revenues from incremental property taxes
will service them.
In other instances, developer-financed TIFs use
conventional loans to developers for infrastructural
improvements. Once TIF revenues become available,
the developers are reimbursed. In some cases, the
TIF district’s primary purpose is to lower private
investors costs; TIF funds are then used to create a
development-subsidy TIF in which payments to private
developers exceed developers’ private expenditures
on public investments.
Often, TIF financing involves other sources of revenue,
including state or federal matching funds or, in some
cases, other tax revenues. Unfortunately, there is little
data on the relative use of these different financing
mechanisms, but anecdotal information suggests
that both TIF bonds and pay-as-you-go financing are
used extensively. Weber (2010) describes the some-
times-complex TIF funding mechanisms used
in Chicago.
TIF statutes commonly require a finding of “blight”
as a condition to establish some or all types of TIF
districts. For example, Maines statute requires that
“[at] least 25%, by area, of the real property within a
development district . . . must be blighted” or meet
one of two other possible criteria (Maine Legislature
Revised Statutes 2017). The Tax Increment Financing
Act in Texas does not require an explicit finding of
“blight,” but it does require that an area contains “a
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 9
The Case apartment building, an infill
development in Dallas, has attracted
more residents to the Deep Ellum District.
Photo: City of Dallas, Office of Economic
Development.
substantial number of substandard, slum, deteriorated,
or deteriorating structures or that the area meets
various other conditions.
Individual states sometimes require proof prior to the
creation of a TIF district that the planned development
would not occur “but for the establishment of a TIF dis-
trict. For example, the Wisconsin legislation (in section
66.1105(4m)(c)1.a) requires that the decision to approve
or deny a proposed TIF depends in part on “whether the
development expected in the tax incremental district
would occur without the use of tax incremental financ-
ing” (Wisconsin State Legislature 2018). In Indiana,
allocation of TIF revenues requires “a specific finding
of fact, supported by evidence, that the adoption of the
allocation provision will result in new property taxes in
the area that would not have been generated but for the
adoption of the allocation provision (General Assembly
of the State of Indiana 2014).
Once a TIF district is operating, revenue can be spent in
a variety of ways. For example, the City of Chicago 2016
Annual Financial Analysis reports that, between 2009
and 2015, about 60 percent of TIF expenditures went to
economic development or infrastructure. Most of the
rest was directed to city facilities for sister agencies,
such as the parks and the school district, and
about 10 percent was spent in direct support of
residential development.
How Does a TIF District Work
in Practice?
The operation of a TIF district might be more fully
understood through the example of an actual TIF
district. In June 2005, the city council of Dallas,
Texas, passed an ordinance creating the Deep Ellum
TIF District. This particular district covers a mixed
residential, commercial, and industrial area of
about 157 acres near downtown Dallas; in 2008, the
city amended the boundaries to include about ten
additional acres. At the time of its creation, the total
appraised value of taxable real property in the TIF
district was approximately $108 million.
The project was designed to facilitate 18 new real
estate projects and about $400 million in new tax-
able private investment, as well as increased transit
use and improved environmental outcomes. Planned
TIF district expenditures of more than $27 million
will be financed by tax revenues on “incremental
10 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
real estate value in the district. The TIF district is
scheduled to terminate after 22 years in 2027—or
sooner, if revenue sufficient to fund the proposed TIF
projects accrues faster. Figure 2 shows a map of this
TIF district.
The inset map shows the location of the district within
the city of Dallas and the larger map shows detail
within the district.
The TIF project plan calls for mixed-use development
including offices, residences, stores, and hotels based
on the expectation this will generate increases in
assessed value that will then generate increases in
property tax revenue.
Table 1 is from the official project plan for the Deep El-
lum TIF District and shows projected taxable assessed
property values, increments of assessed value (called
anticipated captured value”), and sources of property
tax revenue for each year of the TIF district’s projected
life. Column 2 of that table shows that actual taxable
property values were about $108 million when the
district was created in 2005. As shown in column 3,
property value grew by about $6 million in 2006 (to
about $114 million) and by an additional $10 million
dollars in 2007 (to about $124 million). Property value
is then projected to grow each year after that for the
life of the project. Columns 4 and 5 show the amount
of property tax revenue derived from the increments
of assessed value and designated for use in the TIF
district. Beginning in 2008, revenue that would oth-
erwise have gone to either the City of Dallas or Dallas
County instead went to the TIF district. That year, the
increment in assessed values of $42.9 million would
have generated about $273,000 for the TIF district,
rather than the City of Dallas (an effective tax rate of
0.6 percent). An additional $54,000 (an effective tax
rate of 0.1 percent) that would have gone to Dallas
County also became TIF district revenue.
Figure 2
Deep Ellum TIF District Map
Source: City of Dallas, Office of Economic Development (2014).
Deep Ellum TIF Parcels
Deep Ellum TIF Boundary
Rail Station
DART Green Line
Freeway or Tollway
Highway
Arterial
Local Road
Disclaimer: This product is for informational purposes and may not have been prepared for
or be suitable for legal, engineering, or surveying purposes. It does not represent an on-the-
ground survey and represents only the approximate relative location of property boundaries.
10 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 11
Table 1
Annual Real Property Appraisals and City/County Tax to the TIF Fund (Deep Ellum TIF District)
Tax
Year
Property
Value Total
Anticipated
Captured Value
TIF Contribution
City of Dallas
TIF Contribution
Dallas County
Total TIF
Contribution
Total TIF 2006
NPV @ 4.00%
2005
$107,990,540
2006
$114,140,302 $6,149,762 $0 $0 $0 $0
2007
$124,590,053 $16,599,513 $0 $0 $0 $0
2008
$150,935,989 $42,945,449 $273,011 $53,877 $326,888 $290,602
2009
$168,506,948 $60,516,408 $384,712 $75,921 $460,633 $684,353
2010
$402,025,968 $294,035,428 $1,869,227 $368,882 $2,238,109 $2,523,916
2011
$425,967,142 $ 317,976,602 $2,021,425 $398,918 $2,420,343* $4,436,748
2012
$509,592,727 $4 01,602,187 $2,553,945 $503,830 $3,0 57,775* $6,759,722
2013
$5 31,297,766 $423,307,226 $2,691,028 $531,060 $3,222,088 $9,114,070
2014
$539,267,233 $431,276,693 $2,741,691 $541,058 $3,282,749 $11,420,485
2015
$568,993,295 $461,002,755 $2,930,664 $578,351 $3,509,015 $13,791,050
2016
$577,528,194 $469,537,654 $2,984,921 $589,058 $3,573,979* $16,112,639
2017
$586,191,117* $478,200,577 $3,039,993 $599,927 $3,639,920* $18,386,122
2018
$594,983,984 $486,993,444 $3,095,890 $610,958 $3,706,848 $20,612,359
2019
$615,253,167 $507,262,627 $3,224,745 $636,386 $ 3,861,131 $22,842,066
2020
$624,481,964 $516,491,424 $3,283,413 $647,964 $3,931,377* $25,025,020
2021
$633,849,194 $525,858,654 $3,342,962 $659,716 $4,002,678 $ 27,162,08 3
2022
$643,356,932 $535,366,392 $0 $0 $0 $27,162, 0 83
2023
$653,007,286 $545,016,746 $0 $0 $0 $ 27,162,083
2024
$662,802,395 $554,811,855 $0 $0 $0 $27,162,08 3
2025
$672,744,431 $564,753,891 $0 $0 $0 $ 27,162,083
2026
$682,835,597 $574,845,057 $0 $0 $0 $27,162, 0 83
2027
$693,078,131 $5 85 ,0 87,591 $0 $0 $0 $27,162,08 3
2028
$703,474,303 $595,483,763 $0 $0 $0 $ 27,162,0 83
2029
$714,026,418 $606,035,878 $0 $0 $0 $27,162,0 83
2030
$724,736,814 $616,746,274 $0 $0 $0 $27,162,0 83
2031
$735,607,866 $627,617,326 $0 $0 $0 $27,162, 0 83
2032
$746,641,984 $638,651,444 $0 $0 $0 $27,162,08 3
2033
$757,8 41,614 $649,851,074 $0 $0 $0 $27,162,083
2034
$769,209,238 $661,218,698 $0 $0 $0 $27,162, 0 83
2035
$780,747,377 $672,756,837 $0 $0 $0 $ 27,162,083
TOTAL
During
TIF
$34,437,627* $6,795,906 $41,233,533* $27,162,083
Assumptions:
The city of Dallas is expected to participate in the Deep Ellum TIF District for a period of 19 years beginning in 2008 at a rate of 85%. Dallas County
is expected to participate in the Deep Ellum TIF District for a period of 19 years beginning in 2008 at a rate of 55%. The tax rate is assumed constant
at 2005 rate. The actual rate will vary annually. Tax appraisals are for January 1 of the year. Levies occur by September 30 of the year. Tax receipts
generally occur 1213 months after appraisal. Property value estimates assume 1.5% annual property appreciation and 3% annual inflation.
Source: City of Dallas, Office of Economic Development (2011, 2014).
* Figures corrected by the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 11
12 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
The TIF project plan assumes that the effective
property tax rates charged by Dallas City and
County remain constant (at 0.6 percent and 0.1
percent, respectively) for the life of the project and
generate each year’s revenues based on expected
increases in incremental assessed values. In these
projections, the TIF district will continue to receive
revenue until 2021, at which time sufficient reve-
nues will have been raised, according to projections,
to support expenditures planned for the TIF district.
Should the TIF district generate sufficient revenues
earlier, the increment would revert back to the tax
base of the overlying governments of Dallas City and
County. If effective tax rates or rates of real estate
value growth differ from those assumed in the
project plan, revenue raised by the TIF district will
also differ.
Note that the formation of the TIF district has no
impact on the property tax liabilities of real estate
owners in the TIF district. That is, TIF is neither a
property tax break nor an increase. Rather, TIF is a
method for financing public expenditures that may
then promote economic development. Of course,
to the extent that TIF districts divert property tax
revenue that otherwise would have been available
to other areas or uses, TIF may result in higher taxes
or lower services elsewhere, depending on how
overlying governments, such as school and special
districts, respond.
TIF IS NOT ADDITIONAL
LAND VALUE CAPTURE
Land value capture is a policy approach that
enables communities to recover and reinvest
land value increases that result from public
investment and other government actions.
Since well-functioning property tax systems
base obligations on the market value of real
estate, the property tax can be an important
form of land value capture (http://www.
lincolninst.edu/key-issues/value-capture-
property-tax).
Because TIF diverts revenue from real estate
appreciation that may in part be due to public
investment, some observers may erroneously
believe that TIF is a land value capture tool
separate from the property tax.
The property tax liability of property owners
in TIF projects is the same as in projects
using other funding mechanisms. Because of
that, the general public “captures no more
of the value created by public investments
in a TIF district than it would without the
TIF district. In fact, if some TIF revenues are
used to subsidize private activity, as is the
usual case, TIF is more properly a device that
“transfers value to, rather than captures
value from, the private sector.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 13
CHAPTER 2
Potential Benefits and Pitfalls
Some of the most important tools used by local governments
to shape land use and encourage economic development
are not always recognized for their direct effect on economic
growth. These tools include public expenditures to promote
physical infrastructure, such as streets, bridges, and lighting,
and social infrastructure, such as schools, job training,
police, and fire services. State and local governments often
also have access to property tax–related tools, including
incentives and special assessment districts (Kenyon, Langley,
and Paquin 2012). In every state except Arizona, TIF is yet
another economic development tool available to local policy
makers who must weigh the benefits and problems of TIF in
deciding how to design and apply it.
Local businesses like the Murray Street
Coffee Shop increase activity in the
Deep Ellum TIF District in Dallas, Texas.
Photo: City of Dallas, Office of Economic
Development.
14 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
State legislators and local officials alike should first
ask how TIF would best promote public well-being and
what potential pitfalls its use might create. Careful
consideration and a review of the evidence shows that
TIF has the potential to be a constructive and positive
force—but is also vulnerable to abuse, as this report
will consider.
What Are the Potential
Benefits of TIF?
TIF can promote credible commitment between
government and private parties that might not
otherwise be possible.
TIF is not a property tax break, but it represents a
deviation from the usual budgetary process. Most
noncapital government expenditures on economic
development go through an annual appropriation
cycle and must compete with other spending priorities
for the support of a city council or similar govern-
ing body. Such revenues are explicitly appropriated,
whereas TIF district revenues are tax expenditures
(i.e., tax revenues diverted before they reach overly-
ing governments) requiring no explicit appropriation
once government officials initiate the TIF district. The
justification for this dedicated treatment of TIF funds
is that TIF is both a self-financing and an incentive-
compatible mechanism for funding economic devel-
opment. At least in principle, the most important and
distinctive feature of TIF is that the revenues used to
fund economic development are generated by that
same economic development.
Imagine a real estate developer negotiating with a
city government about a potential development. The
developer would like the government to make some
infrastructure investments that would increase the
value of her property and help ensure that her private
investment will be economically rewarding. The gov-
ernment would like the developer to make a private
investment first, to increase the property tax base,
enhance the quality of life in the community, and help
ensure that the developer will not renege on or reduce
her commitment after public investments are made.
TIF provides a potential way around this dilemma: The
government can promise the developer that property
tax revenue generated by any increase in real estate
value resulting from her private investment will be
dedicated for the sole use of public investment to
enhance the project. With this promise, lenders can be
persuaded to buy bonds backed by future TIF district
tax revenues, and those bonds can be used to pay for
public investments even before private investments
are made. The key is the credible and legal commit-
ment by the government to direct all future revenues
to economic development projects within the TIF
district. If the developer fails to make the promised
private investments, property values will not appre-
ciate enough to service the bonds backing the public
investment, resulting in default or the slowing (or
halting) of public investment. Either outcome could
severely reduce the value of the private investment.
The developer’s incentive to maximize the value of
the private investment is compatible with the govern-
ment’s incentive to increase the property tax base and
improve the quality of life.
TIF ensures mutual commitment and mutual benefit.
Without it, the government officials could make a ver-
bal commitment to the developer, promising to devote
revenue from incremental taxable property to eco-
nomic development projects within a given area. But
government officials change over time, and potential
lenders and developers might worry that the govern-
ment’s commitment will not prove totally credible or
sustainable in the longer term. This might make them
reluctant to invest in the project.
TIF may facilitate widespread political support for
public investments with localized benefits.
Imagine a public investment that will benefit only a
small fraction of a municipality, like infrastructure for
a small shopping mall. Under ordinary circumstances,
citywide taxpayers may oppose this investment, even
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 15
when the benefit to the immediately surrounding
neighborhood is greater than the public cost, because
the increase in taxes to pay for the investment will be
greater than the benefit received for residents outside
the affected neighborhood. TIF presents a potential
mechanism to circumvent this problem because it
allows the government making the investment to cap-
ture some revenues that otherwise would have gone
to overlying governments while not unduly burdening
unaffected taxpayers. In this way, Brueckner (2001)
argues, TIF may improve the allocation of resources.
That said, local governments may accomplish similar
goals with alternative tools such as special assess-
ments—where tax rates rise only in a specific area to
accomplish a specific goal.
What Are the Potential
Pitfalls of TIF?
TIF may capture revenues that would otherwise go to
overlying governments.
Most states allow cities to establish TIF districts with-
out consent from overlying governments, such as coun-
ties and school districts, that may depend on the same
tax base. Unfortunately, these rules set up potentially
perverse incentives by allowing cities to claim property
tax revenue that they might not have received in the
absence of TIF. Establishing a TIF district allows city
governments to capture property tax revenue generat-
ed by non-TIF increases in taxable assessed values—
revenue that otherwise would have gone to special
districts and other overlying governments. In this case,
even though the TIF district fails to stimulate economic
development, it still benefits the city government that
established it.
To avert these perverse incentives, many states include
a “but for” clause in their TIF-enabling legislation. As a
Minnesota source explains,
[The] Tax Increment Financing Act requires that
before a city establishes a TIF district, the govern-
ing body must find that, “the proposed devel-
opment or redevelopment, in the opinion of the
municipality, would not reasonably be expected to
occur solely through private investment within the
reasonably foreseeable future. This requirement,
known as the “but for” test, is intended to restrict
the use of TIF. (Minnesota Office of the Legislative
Auditor, Program Evaluation Division 1996, 71)
If it were true that no real estate appreciation would
have occurred in the TIF district “but for” the TIF activ-
ities, overlying governments, such as school districts
and other special districts, would get the same amount
of property tax revenue that they would have received
without the TIF district. In this case, the TIF designation
harms no one and potentially benefits both the private
developer and the city government creating the TIF dis-
trict. Eventually, the overlying governments also benefit
when the TIF district is retired and taxable appraised
values revert to their tax bases.
In practice, however, the “but for” requirement has
been interpreted in a variety of ways. At most, it has
produced only a very loose constraint on the funding of
development activities. Minnesotas legislative auditor
found that Minnesota cities “interpret the ‘but for
requirement in a variety of ways. Reasons for providing
TIF-based assistance to development included:
unusual circumstances made the project too
expensive to develop otherwise;
even though the development would likely occur
without TIF assistance, it would not occur at a
The key is the credible and legal
commitment by the government to
direct all future revenues to economic
development projects within the
TIF district.
16 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
location consistent with the citys development
goals absent the assistance;
the development would occur sooner with
TIF assistance;
the development would be bigger or better with
TIF assistance;
a company threatened to go elsewhere if it did
not get TIF assistance; and
TIF allowed the city to make public
improvements that would not otherwise
have happened.
The auditor concluded that given the variety of
interpretations available, it is difficult to imagine a
development that would not meet the ‘but for’ test
in some sense (Minnesota Office of the Legislative
Auditor, Program Evaluation Division 1996, 73).
TIF can make governments financial situations and
transactions less transparent and allow evasion
of political constraints on using public funds for
private purposes.
Because TIF revenues can be used only for limited
purposes, they are usually sequestered in special
funds, which contain a mixture of money that oth-
erwise would have gone to the city that established
the TIF and overlying governments. TIF revenues are
also temporary, as the TIF district expires at some
point. TIF districts use a variety of mechanisms to
document and account for the receipt of these funds.
In the most transparent cases, TIF authorities make
publicly available the TIF plan and a record of annual
TIF district receipts and expenditures, sometimes
with a great deal of detail, perhaps even including
account balances and fund transfers. Many TIF
districts fall far short of these ideals, however, or
provide materials late.
Indeed, even in the best cases, the existence of a
separate set of funds—outside cities operating
accounts and generally not reflected in their annual
financial reports—may obscure, delay, or prohibit a
comprehensive picture of a city’s financial condition.
If TIF district expenditures are not documented in de-
tail, observers may also suspect misuse of funds, such
as money funneled to political allies in particularly
egregious cases. TIF district budget transparency has
been a particularly controversial issue in cities such as
Chicago, which has many TIF districts and thus large,
sometimes temporary, reserves of TIF funds. This is
discussed more in chapter 5.
TIF can facilitate unproductive fiscal competition
between neighboring jurisdictions.
Business tax incentives in general—and TIF in
particular—are vulnerable to overuse if potential
beneficiaries can stimulate a virtual or actual bid-
ding war among competing governments. A busi-
ness that is considering expansion or relocation
may use the existence of tax incentive programs to
obtain benefits or threaten to leave to obtain more,
even when a location would be the businesss most
profitable option even without the benefits. As TIF
policies usually allow many cities to offer TIF, busi-
nesses may find several negotiating partners.
Economic theory suggests that under some con-
ditions such negotiations can reduce economic
efficiency. Recent empirical research shows that
business tax incentives in general are not well
targeted and often do little to stimulate economic
activity (Bartik 2017; Florida 2017; Kenyon, Langley,
and Paquin 2012). Evidence on the specific impact
of TIF districts is discussed in chapter 7 and shows
mixed results, with some studies showing a net
stimulus but others showing little or no effects.
TIF is yet another economic development
tool available to local policy makers who
must weigh the benefits and problems
of TIF in deciding how to design and
apply it.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 17
CHAPTER 3
Case Studies
This chapter presents three case studies demonstrating
TIF use in a variety of areas: a large southern city (Atlanta,
Georgia), a rural western area (Jefferson County, Montana),
and an older Midwestern city (St. Louis, Missouri). While
three cases cannot fully illustrate the vast number of ways
and situations in which TIF has been used, these examples
provide some sense of the tools diversity and illuminate
many of its strengths and weakness.
Cortex Innovation District in St. Louis is
the Midwest’s premier hub of bioscience
and technology, serving start-up programs
and established companies. The master
plan provides for mixed-use development
for research, office, clinical, residential,
hospitality, and retail spaces. Photo:
Cortex Innovation Community.
18 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Case Study 1: Atlanta BeltLine
Tax Allocation District, Georgia
This case illustrates how TIF can be used to support
a community vision that requires a prolonged period
of gestation and demands substantial public and
private investment. It also shows how plans can
evolve over time.
BACKGROUND
In 1999, Ryan Gravel, a graduate student at Georgia
Tech, proposed a new transit system linking multiple
Atlanta neighborhoods along old rail corridors
surrounding the city. The idea gradually gained
grassroots support, and a steering committee study
found that a tax allocation district (TAD)—Georgias
name for a TIF—could cover 60 percent of project
costs without requiring a tax increase. In 2004, the
Atlanta BeltLine TAD was approved by the city council
with the support of the mayor. In 2006, Invest Atlanta,
formerly the Atlanta Development Authority, formed
the Atlanta BeltLine Inc., and a $60 million capital
campaign was launched to support the project. By
2008, the capital campaign was 50 percent complete,
and more than $60 million dollars of bonds were sold
to investors with backing of TIF revenues. Over the
next several years, the BeltLine project increasingly
emphasized environmental responsibility, equitable
development, and affordable housing. Construction
proceeded on several transportation, recreation, and
housing projects.
Though many of the Atlanta BeltLine TAD’s goals are
comparable to those of other TIF projects throughout
the country, the BeltLine is unusual for its shape and
scope: This particular district encircles the city of
Atlanta and includes a 22-mile transit system, many
miles of trails, and numerous new and affordable
housing units (figure 3).
PLANS
The original 2005 Atlanta BeltLine Redevelopment
Plan, created by Atlanta Development, aimed to
change the pattern of spotty regional growth by
attracting and organizing future growth through
creating parks, transit, and trails. The plan focused
on acquiring land, creating trails and green spaces,
building a new transit system and improving exist-
ing transportation, developing affordable workforce
housing, and contributing to Atlanta Public Schools. In
2013, Atlanta BeltLine Inc.s board of directors unani-
mously approved the 2030 Strategic Implementation
Plan (SIP). The project was supposed to be executed
in stages. The SIP prioritized certain projects and laid
out the funding mechanisms. The majority of fund-
ing was directed toward transit improvements even
though these projects are set to begin later in the pro-
cess. Atlanta Beltline Inc. will develop trails and parks
first, using bond money, to create the tax increment
necessary to pay for the transit projects.
Figure 3
Map of Atlanta Tax Allocation District (TAD)
Atlanta BeltLine Corridor Atlanta BeltLine Tax
Allocation District (TAD)
Source: Atlanta BeltLine, Inc. (2018).
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 19
FUNDING
The SIP projected that the plan could be completed by
2030 and would cost $4.4 billion in total. Throughout
the duration of the project, the TAD funds are expected
to be the most substantial source of funding, account-
ing for about 33 percent of the total cost. Apprecia-
tion should generate approximately $1.5 billion in tax
increment revenue—a conservative estimate with
prices pegged to inflation. The next largest source of
revenue is expected to come from the federal govern-
ment—especially U.S. Department of Transportation
funding—that will be used specifically for BeltLine
transit projects. The remaining funding will come from
a combination of local sources, such as a new parking
tax and private donations. According to a project web-
site, the BeltLine has already received over $40 million
from private donations and $25 million from federal
sources. During the first five years of Atlanta BeltLine
Inc. (2006–2011), $337 million was expended, about
35 percent of which came from the tax increment.
Another 44 percent came from city funds, with the
remainder from federal funds, philanthropies, or other
sources (Atlanta BeltLine 2013).
PROJECTS
The Atlanta BeltLine 2015 and 2016 annual reports
featured a “performance dashboard” that showed
mixed results. By 2015, the project had raised $449
million out of a total target investment of $2.8 to $4.8
billion by 2030. The project’s control of trail and transit
real estate was on time, but completed transit proj-
ects, streetscape construction, and affordable housing
were all behind schedule. In November 2016, Atlanta
voters approved two new taxes designed to speed
progress on the project: an extra one-half of a cent
sales tax to provide revenues for public transportation
and an additional four-tenths of a cent local option
sales tax to provide additional revenue to purchase
easements for the Atlanta BeltLine loop.
OPPOSITION
Though much of the Atlanta BeltLine project has
met with support, some local opposition has arisen
throughout its lifetime. In the early planning stages, a
resident sued the city on constitutional grounds, claim-
ing that the use of school taxes for security on bonds
violated the educational purpose clause of Georgias
constitution. The Georgia Supreme Court agreed and
declared the TAD’s use of public school taxes unconsti-
tutional, dealing an early blow to the project. Following
this ruling, however, the Georgia General Assembly
amended the state constitution to strengthen the
Redevelopment Powers Law, effectively bolstering the
legitimacy of TAD funding. Now officially constitutional,
the project was able to continue with its original main
funding source.
In 2008, the Fulton County Taxpayers Foundation filed
a lawsuit against the City of Atlanta and its public
school system, seeking an injunction to again prevent
the use of school property tax revenues for the TAD.
Despite the recent amendment, the Foundation argued,
the Educational Purpose Clause remained intact. In
a unanimous vote, the Georgia Supreme Court ruled
that the use of TAD financing for the BeltLine and other
TAD projects in the state is constitutional, technically
overturning the court’s prior decision in light of the new
constitutional amendment and allowing Georgias TIF
mechanism to continue funding a range of projects.
The BeltLine project, with the confluence of concerns
about gentrification, government spending, and issues
of race, illustrates how a TIF mechanism can become
so closely scrutinized.
20 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Case Study 2: Jefferson
County, Montana
This case illustrates how a small county used TIF to
cushion community transition when one source of
economic activity slowed, requiring new sources of
jobs and income.
BACKGROUND
Located in southwestern Montana, Jefferson County is
home to 11,406 people who enjoy a median household
income of $60,863—well above the state median of
$46,230. The county includes Boulder, Jefferson City,
Clancy, Montana City, and Whitehall, as well as several
smaller towns. The county’s economy depends largely
on its natural resources, including agriculture, forestry,
and mining.
The Golden Sunlight Mine, a long-standing presence
in the local economy employing about 200 people from
the county, was expected to exhaust its resources and
close sometime in 2015. In 2009, anticipating this loss
of employment, Jefferson County and the Jefferson
Local Development Corporation (JLDC), in partner-
ship with mine operator Barrick Gold, proposed the
implementation of a TIFID (Tax Increment Financing
Industrial District). The mine did not close in 2015 and
is expected to continue operation into the next decade.
Economic development efforts have continued on the
land surrounding the mine.
Until 1989, Montana allowed TIF only for rehabilitation
within designated urban renewal areas. In that year, the
state legislature amended the Montana Urban Renewal
Law to allow TIFIDs to be used to develop and retain
“value-added” companies—that is, companies that
convert raw materials into more valuable products that
can be traded. With this in mind, the Jefferson
Local Development Corporation formulated and
submitted a new plan for the Sunlight District.
PLANS
The 2009 Jefferson County TIFID Plan, which proposed
the Sunlight Business Park, outlined the types of indus-
trial developments being sought and analyzed related
infrastructure needs. First, the plan identified five key
potential industries particularly suited for the economy
and the needs of both Jefferson County and Montana
as a whole. These industries included metal ore mining,
general manufacturing, food manufacturing, engineer-
ing services, and electrical power generation (except
hydroelectric, fossil fuel, and nuclear).
The plan also identified a significant deficiency in
usable infrastructure. The only roads identified in the
district were described in the plan as “primitive” and
“unpaved. The district had an electrical transmission
line and an electrical substation line but no gas or
electrical supply lines outside of the mining properties.
Additionally, there were no water supply or treatment
lines outside of the Golden Sunlight Mine. TIFID funds
would be needed to build and extend the infrastructure
for development to occur within the TIFID.
FUNDING
The proposed development projects would be funded
through annual tax increment appropriation and con-
ventional financing through Jefferson County but man-
aged by the JLDC. The plan emphasized partnership
development including existing partnerships among
Jefferson County, the JLDC, and Barrick Gold. However,
the JLDC planned to seek additional partners, includ-
ing state and federal government funding programs, to
speed up and ease the development process.
PROGRESS
The JLDC used the dedicated local portion of revenues
from a tax on metal mining (in this case, gold) to secure
a $655,000 loan from the county to fund infrastructure
in the TIFID. The Great Recession discouraged new
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 21
In 2015, Jefferson County, Montana implemented a Tax Increment
Financing Industrial District (TIFID) to compensate for the
expected closing of the Golden Sunlight Mine. Photo: Mark Briggs,
Barrick Gold of North America, Inc.
business activity in the region, however, and during the
first few years of operation there was little new econom-
ic activity in the Sunlight TIFID. In 2013, Jefferson Coun-
ty amended the Sunlight TIFID Plan yet again to include
a Tax Increment Financing Revolving Loan Program. The
new program was funded with incremental property tax
revenues. The JLDC intended to entice new business
development to the area. The revolving loan fund is
perpetual and can continue even after the TIFID expires.
Actual construction in the TIFID area did not commence
until May 2014, when the county broke ground on a new
business park.
In the five-year period between the original Sunlight
TIFID proposal and the 2014 groundbreaking, Jefferson
County and the JLDC recognized the increasing impor-
tance of rapid Internet access for business development
and decided to use the TIFID to reinvent and invigorate
the local economy. This caused a shift away from the
original proposal, which focused on resource-oriented
development, to a plan to attract more high-tech com-
panies and jobs, which in turn altered the original plans
of the Sunlight Business Park. By early 2017, three units,
including office and warehouse space, had been built
in the business park and were occupied by businesses
focused on the Internet, wind energy, and medicine. One
company was a business already established within the
county, that moved to the park and expanded employ-
ment to take advantage of faster Internet service. The
wind-energy firm, LGT Advanced Technology Limited from
the United Kingdom, also moved in. By early 2017, the
companies had added only a small number of jobs, but
the JLDC remains hopeful that future growth will create
more well-paying, permanent jobs in the next few years.
CHALLENGES
Since its conception, the Sunlight TIFID was unique-
ly poised for success. Jefferson County had a built-in
organization to manage and help plan the TIFID with the
JLDC as well as the commitment and support of one of
the largest corporate entities in the area—Barrick Gold,
which operates the Sunlight Gold Mine. The company has
demonstrated its commitment to ensuring the county’s
economic stability. For example, the company leases the
land for the Sunlight Business Park to Jefferson County—
a total of 48 acres—for just $10 annually.
Loans from the county, supported by dedicated revenues
from the metals tax, were used to create the infrastruc-
ture needed to make the business park operable, as
well as to finance construction of the office building and
warehouse. Through early 2017, development in the TIFID
was slow—perhaps because of a lack of advertising and
recruiting due to the limited resources available to the
JLDC. This illustrates the “chicken and egg” problems that
can arise with “pay-as-you-go TIF, which must generate
revenues through new tax increments provided to the
district. The lack of advertising contributed to the slow
real estate development, and subsequent tax increments
provided insufficient funds to support advertisement and
recruitment. This, along with poor economic conditions
during the time the TIFID was started, resulted in slow
initial development in the area (Harrington 2017).
Despite this, there has been some development in the
TIFID, which has benefited the community beyond its geo-
graphic boundaries by making possible the expansion of
fiber lines to support rapid Internet service in surrounding
communities. Proponents hope that this will enhance
business opportunities in the region in the long run.
22 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Case Study 3:
St. Louis, Missouri
This case study illustrates the use of TIF in a big
city facing severe fiscal, economic, and competitive
challenges. Missouri’s TIF law, though similar to other
states in some respects, uses unusual mechanisms
and language.
BACKGROUND
In Missouri, a TIF district technically freezes property
taxes within the district but requires that property own-
ers make Payments in Lieu of Taxes (PILOTS) to a special
fund—at a rate of 100 percent. These PILOTS should not
be confused with payments of the same name some-
times made by universities and charitable organizations
that are exempt from property taxes in other states
(Langley, Kenyon, and Ballin 2012). Missouri also allows
for up to 50 percent of local income and sales tax reve-
nue generated by new economic activity to be captured
and diverted into the special-allocation fund, which is
then used to reimburse the developer or to retire debt
from bonds used to finance development.
By early 2016, there were well over 100 TIF projects in
the city of St. Louis alone, making it among the most
active TIF users in the United States. A local research
and advocacy group, Better Together St. Louis, found
that $2 billion of public tax dollars had been diverted to
developers in the region through TIF. The same groups
2011 survey of TIFs in the St. Louis metropolitan area
found that about 80 percent of TIF projects in the region
were retail-oriented development projects; residential
development was another common use of TIF in the area
(Coleman and Murphy 2014).
With so many TIF districts in St. Louis, however, mixed
results are not surprising.
STORY OF SUCCESS: INNOVATION
DISTRICT REDEVELOPMENT AREA
Approved in 2012, the Cortex Redevelopment Plan, also
known as the Innovation District Redevelopment Area,
was one of the largest TIF-supported undertakings in
the St. Louis area. The plan included developing offices,
research facilities, stores, a healthcare facility, a recre-
ational open space, and a new public-transit station—
all on largely vacant land that had resulted in part from
the loss of jobs and population in the area. The plan is
estimated to be completed in 2024 and projected to cost
upward of $2 billion, including $158.2 million funded
by TIF.
Despite its relatively new status, Cortex is considered
one of the most successful TIF undertakings in St. Louis.
During Phase I of the project, the Cortex Innovation
District used around $10 million in TIF funds to inject
$155 million of investment and to create 955 technology
and management jobs in the area. Phase II is expected
to spur $186 million of investment within the district, as
well as 1,400 more well-paying, permanent jobs. Over
the course of the 25-year project, the Cortex Innovation
District is expected to produce an estimated 2,400 jobs.
By late 2016, the Cortex District reportedly had 4,100
people working for 260 companies and was adding
additional economic activity including new hotels,
apartments, and retailers (Barker and Bryant 2016).
Unlike many TIF projects in the city, the Cortex Innova-
tion District has managed to procure outside funding
and partners. Cortex has paired with two major universi-
ties in the area—Washington University in St. Louis and
University of Missouri—as well as private, nonprofit,
and government organizations. Though TIF remains inte-
gral to the district’s further development, these outside
partnerships have helped the Innovation District to
thrive. The use of TIF in St. Louis reflects the urgency felt
by public, private, and nonprofit leaders to find a path to
regeneration after devastating losses of population and
jobs that left wide swaths of vacant and underutilized
urban land.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 23
STORIES OF FAILURE:
GRAND AND SHENANDOAH
Not all of the TIF districts in St. Louis have been as
successful as the Cortex TIF district. A 2018 summary
of St. Louis TIF districts on the citys website lists
approximately 180 TIF districts (St. Louis Development
Corporation 2018). Most of these are still active in 2018,
so it is difficult to render a final judgment on their
success. Roughly 20 of the TIF districts were terminat-
ed before completion, and approximately 16 ultimately
failed to get approval after potential developers filed
applications with the redevelopment agency.
The Grand and Shenandoah District, approved in
February 2007, was terminated before completion.
The city ordinance creating the TIF district described
a plan to use $2.5 million in TIF borrowing in addition
to other revenues to finance more than $7 million of
redevelopment on two blighted parcels at the corner
of Grand and Shenandoah Avenues. The plan called
for the demolition of a building that formerly housed
a YMCA and the construction of a new, mixed-use
commercial building with 14,000 square feet of retail
space and 16,000 square feet of office space. The plan
also involved rehabilitating a 1895 historic building
once used as a high-end restaurant, before it fell into
disrepair. The citys 2007 annual report on the project
filed with the Missouri state auditor estimated that 125
jobs would be created (Missouri Office of State Auditor
2018). The developer, however, could not secure the
needed preconstruction leasing commitments and,
therefore, was unable to get financing for the project.
The TIF district was dissolved in 2016 without creating
any new jobs and with only approximately $6,000 in tax
revenues since its inception. After this TIF failed, the
city was later able to attract new developers by using
tax abatements and, by early 2018, renovation on the
historic restaurant was underway and additional con-
struction was planned at the site of the former YMCA.
Studies have found that jobs created in TIF districts
can displace jobs in competing businesses that do not
Washington University in St. Louis and the University of Missouri
among others partnered with Cortex to help launch the Innovation
District. Photo: bluepoint951/Flickr CC BY-NC-SA 2.0.
thrive or survive in surrounding neighborhoods. Thus,
one neighborhood may benefit while the surrounding
areas suffer, resulting in minimal net benefit to the city
as a whole (Coleman and Murphy 2014). Another study
noted the sharp decline of small retail stores employing
10 or fewer people, suggesting that large businesses
gained sales and employees at the expense of smaller
local businesses (East-West Gateway Council of Govern-
ment 2011). Coleman and Murphy (2014) argue that this
trend indicates there is less room for local entrepre-
neurs in the market and indicates an increased likeli-
hood of reduced profits for the City of St. Louis.
Literature suggests that these unsuccessful projects
failed because over 80 percent of TIFs are for retail
projects that serve a local market. Unlike Cortex, these
retail jobs are not being created by TIF; they are merely
being displaced. Other projects may be less successful
due to a strong dependence on TIF financing rather than
community partnerships that would help ensure long-
term success.
24 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
CHAPTER 4
Use and Implementation
TIF is a local government program facilitated by state-
enabling legislation with varying state involvement. Some
states, such as Maine, simply verify that proposals for
local TIF districts meet statutory requirements but do
not track or monitor TIF districts once they are created.
Others, such as Illinois, require annual reports on each
TIF district and provide state-level data about TIF use.
Nationwide, TIF has certain common elements (described
in chapter 1), but each state has its own enabling legisla-
tion and regulations for the use of TIF. States set the rules
for establishing and modifying TIF districts, the length of
time they may be in effect, the acceptable uses of funds,
the reporting requirements, and other guidelines.
In Maine, TIF was used to fund the Bath
Iron Works modernization project, which
created a dry dock launching facility.
Photo: Ted Kerwin/Flickr CC BY 2.0.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 25
Early studies documenting state TIF legislation include
Johnson and Kritz (2001), Johnson (2002), and Council
of Development Finance Authorities (2008). As of early
2018, there are two web-based resources that provide
information about TIF rules across the United States.
1. The Council of Development Finance Agencies
(CDFA) has an online Tax Increment Finance
Resource Center (2017) that provides a wealth of
information, though some items are available only
to paying members. The site provides an open-
access state-by-state map that allows users
to click on a U.S. state and obtain a link to that
states TIF statute and summary information about
requirements for district creation, eligible public
costs, financing options, maximum length of dis-
trict, and several other items. (This data excludes
Arizona, which does not allow TIF.)
2. Significant Features of the Property Tax Database
(2018), updated annually and produced through a
partnership of the Lincoln Institute of Land Policy
and the George Washington Institute of Public
Policy, provides a range of information on the
property tax and TIF laws in each state, including
relevant statutes, program names, geographic
requirements, descriptions of incentives, and
more. The website includes information about
TIF programs in each state. The appendix table
in this report (p. 59) is drawn from that website
and contains the most current available informa-
tion about the name of the TIF program in each
state, the allowable duration of TIF districts, the
legal requirements to create a TIF district, the
agencies that must approve TIF districts, and the
requirements for public hearings.
Where Has TIF Been Used?
Both resources focus on the legal authority for TIF, but
neither source provides data on the tools actual use.
National data on TIF use is extremely difficult to com-
pile because many states do not monitor TIF use once
a district is authorized. The International City/County
Management Association (ICMA) has sponsored several
surveys asking local government officials about their
economic development activities. Their 2014 survey
reports that about 42 percent of the 1,148 responding
local governments are using TIF as a source of funding.
Warner and Zheng (2013), Felix and Hines (2013), and
Greenbaum and Landers (2014) all provide analyses of
earlier ICMA surveys and find similar percentages of
respondents offering TIF-type economic development
incentives. However, as Greenbaum and Landers point
out, the response rate to ICMA surveys is generally
relatively low—around 25 percent—and thus may not
be representative of all local governments. Greenbaum
and Landers also find significant regional variation
in the use of TIF by respondents to the ICMAs 2009 sur-
vey, with 74 percent of respondents in the north-central
region reporting use of TIF, compared to only 24 percent
of respondents in the Northeast.
Table 2 (p. 26) provides information about the legal
uses of TIF revenues and estimates of the number of
TIF districts in each state. In some cases, the esti-
mates have been compiled by state authorities and
are quite precise. In other cases, where the state does
not track or report the number of TIF districts, the best
available estimates are reported. Figure 4 maps the
data in column 3 of table 2 (p. 30).
Table 2
Number of TIF Districts and Additional Authorized Uses of TIF Revenues by State
26 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Permitted Development Subsidies Other Public Uses Outside of TIF District
State Program Name
Estimated Number of TIF
Districts in State
Sell or Rent Land Below
Fair Market Value
Construct Buildings
and Facilities
Tax Subsidies
(freezes and
abatements)
Direct Financial
Subsidies (including
reimbursement
for project costs, loans,
and funds for training)
Public Expenditure to
Benefit TIF District
Shared Revenue*
ALABAMA
Tax Increment Districts 10
ALASKA
Improvement Area Projects 1
ARIZONA
N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A
ARKANSAS
Redevelopment Districts 9
CALIFORNIA
Enhanced Infrastructure Financing Districts 743
COLORADO
Tax Increment Financing Districts 140
å
CONNECTICUT
Tax Increment Financing Districts 4
DELAWARE
Municipal Tax Increment Financing Districts 0
FLORIDA
Community Development 222
GEORGIA
Tax Allocation Districts 64
HAWAII
Tax Increment Financing Districts 0
IDAHO
Revenue Allocation Areas 78
ILLINOIS
Tax Increment Allocation Redevelopment Areas 1238
INDIANA
Tax Increment Financing Districts 700–800
IOWA
Urban Renewal Areas 3340
KANSAS
Tax Increment Financing Districts 11
KENTUCKY
Tax Increment Financing Districts 23
LOUISIANA
Tax Increment Development 9
MAINE
Tax Increment Financing Districts 483
MARYLAND
Tax Increment Financing Districts 28
MASSACHUSETTS
District Improvement Financing 2
MICHIGAN
Tax Increment Financing 634
MINNESOTA
Tax Increment Financing 1719
MISSISSIPPI
Tax Increment Financing 25
MISSOURI
Real Property Tax Increment Allocation 468
MONTANA
Tax Increment Financing 50
NEBRASKA
Tax Increment Financing for Redevelopment Projects 828
Permitted Development Subsidies Other Public Uses Outside of TIF District
State Program Name
Estimated Number of TIF
Districts in State
Sell or Rent Land Below
Fair Market Value
Construct Buildings
and Facilities
Tax Subsidies
(freezes and
abatements)
Direct Financial
Subsidies (including
reimbursement
for project costs, loans,
and funds for training)
Public Expenditure to
Benefit TIF District
Shared Revenue*
ALABAMA
Tax Increment Districts 10
ALASKA
Improvement Area Projects 1
ARIZONA
N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A N/A
ARKANSAS
Redevelopment Districts 9
CALIFORNIA
Enhanced Infrastructure Financing Districts 743
COLORADO
Tax Increment Financing Districts 140
å
CONNECTICUT
Tax Increment Financing Districts 4
DELAWARE
Municipal Tax Increment Financing Districts 0
FLORIDA
Community Development 222
GEORGIA
Tax Allocation Districts 64
HAWAII
Tax Increment Financing Districts 0
IDAHO
Revenue Allocation Areas 78
ILLINOIS
Tax Increment Allocation Redevelopment Areas 1238
INDIANA
Tax Increment Financing Districts 700–800
IOWA
Urban Renewal Areas 3340
KANSAS
Tax Increment Financing Districts 11
KENTUCKY
Tax Increment Financing Districts 23
LOUISIANA
Tax Increment Development 9
MAINE
Tax Increment Financing Districts 483
MARYLAND
Tax Increment Financing Districts 28
MASSACHUSETTS
District Improvement Financing 2
MICHIGAN
Tax Increment Financing 634
MINNESOTA
Tax Increment Financing 1719
MISSISSIPPI
Tax Increment Financing 25
MISSOURI
Real Property Tax Increment Allocation 468
MONTANA
Tax Increment Financing 50
NEBRASKA
Tax Increment Financing for Redevelopment Projects 828
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 27
28 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
28 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Table 2, cont’d
Number of TIF Districts and Additional Authorized Uses of TIF Revenues by State
Permitted Development Subsidies Other Public Uses Outside of TIF District
State Program Name
Estimated Number of TIF
Districts in State
Sell or Rent Land
Below
Fair Market Value
Construct Buildings
and Facilities
Tax Subsidies
(freezes and
abatements)
Direct Financial
Subsidies (including
reimbursement
for project costs, loans,
and funds for training)
Public Expenditure to
Benefit TIF District
Shared Revenue*
NEVADA
TIF and Redevelopment Areas 22
NEW HAMPSHIRE
Tax Increment Financing in Development Districts 32
NEW JERSEY
Revenue Allocation District Financing 49
NEW MEXICO
Tax Increment Development Districts 16
NEW YORK
Tax Increment Financing 2
NORTH CAROLINA
Project Development Financing (TIF) 3
NORTH DAKOTA
Tax Increment Financing 48
OHIO
Tax Increment Financing Districts 1278
OKLAHOMA
Tax Increment Financing Districts 48
OREGON
Urban Renewal Plans 244
PENNSYLVANIA
Tax Incremental Financing Districts 100
RHODE ISLAND
Tax Increment Financing Areas 5
SOUTH CAROLINA
Tax Increment Financing for Redevelopment Projects 17
SOUTH DAKOTA
Tax Incremental Districts 172
TENNESSEE
Tax Increment Financing 29
TEXAS
Tax Increment Reinvestment Zones 1378
UTAH
Tax Increment Financing Districts 84
VERMONT
Tax Increment Financing Districts 9
VIRGINIA
Tax Increment Financing Districts 9
WASHINGTON
Tax Increment Financing 38
WEST VIRGINIA
Tax Increment Financing 31
WISCONSIN
Tax Incremental Districts 1241
WYOMING
Tax Increment Financing 10
Table focuses on the most broadly applicable TIFs.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 29
Permitted Development Subsidies Other Public Uses Outside of TIF District
State Program Name
Estimated Number of TIF
Districts in State
Sell or Rent Land
Below
Fair Market Value
Construct Buildings
and Facilities
Tax Subsidies
(freezes and
abatements)
Direct Financial
Subsidies (including
reimbursement
for project costs, loans,
and funds for training)
Public Expenditure to
Benefit TIF District
Shared Revenue*
NEVADA
TIF and Redevelopment Areas 22
NEW HAMPSHIRE
Tax Increment Financing in Development Districts 32
NEW JERSEY
Revenue Allocation District Financing 49
NEW MEXICO
Tax Increment Development Districts 16
NEW YORK
Tax Increment Financing 2
NORTH CAROLINA
Project Development Financing (TIF) 3
NORTH DAKOTA
Tax Increment Financing 48
OHIO
Tax Increment Financing Districts 1278
OKLAHOMA
Tax Increment Financing Districts 48
OREGON
Urban Renewal Plans 244
PENNSYLVANIA
Tax Incremental Financing Districts 100
RHODE ISLAND
Tax Increment Financing Areas 5
SOUTH CAROLINA
Tax Increment Financing for Redevelopment Projects 17
SOUTH DAKOTA
Tax Incremental Districts 172
TENNESSEE
Tax Increment Financing 29
TEXAS
Tax Increment Reinvestment Zones 1378
UTAH
Tax Increment Financing Districts 84
VERMONT
Tax Increment Financing Districts 9
VIRGINIA
Tax Increment Financing Districts 9
WASHINGTON
Tax Increment Financing 38
WEST VIRGINIA
Tax Increment Financing 31
WISCONSIN
Tax Incremental Districts 1241
WYOMING
Tax Increment Financing 10
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 29
Sources: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy and the George Washington Institute of Public Policy (2018); Column 3: Merriman, Qiao, and Zhao (2018).
Shared revenue indicates either initial allocation among jurisdictions and TIF districts or that jurisdiction allows other jurisdictions to opt out. In general,
when TIF districts have sufficient funds for development and debt service, excess funds are returned to the taxing jurisdictions.
*
30 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Figure 4
Estimated Number of TIF Districts by State
Figure 4 illustrates how the use of TIF varies dramati-
cally from state to state. Consistent with Greenbaum
and Landerss (2014) analysis of ICMA data, nearly all
of the Midwestern states make extensive use of TIF. By
contrast, none of the New England states except Maine
use TIF to a large extent. In fact, outside of the Mid-
west, Colorado, Florida, Maine, Oregon, Pennsylvania,
and Texas have 100 or more TIF districts, and Califor-
nia greatly restricts the creation of new TIF districts.
Twelve states (not including Arizona, which prohibits
TIF) have nine or fewer TIF districts. To date, there has
been no published academic work explaining why local
governments in some states use TIF more extensively
than others.
The remainder of table 2 provides information about
acceptable use of TIF revenue. All state TIF statutes
allow TIF revenues to be used to service bonds that are
sold to fund development activities in the TIF district.
TIF funds can be used for other development subsi-
dies in some states including the below-fair-market
sale or rental of real estate to private parties in order
to promote economic development or construction of
facilities within the TIF district, etc. Roughly two-thirds
of the states allow some use of TIF funds for limited
activities outside of physical TIF boundaries.
In some cases, TIF authorities sell bonds and use funds
from property tax revenues on the TIF increment to
service the bond debt. As discussed previously, use of
TIF district-financed debt may allow the TIF authority to
jump-start economic development in the district. Table
3 shows, in general, that states with many TIF districts
also had a large amount of TIF debt. For example, Cali-
fornia, with more than 700 TIF districts, had about $25
billion of TIF bond issues. However, the amount varies
greatly across states: Ohio has even more TIF districts
than California, but TIF districts in Ohio issued only
about $500 million of TIF debt. In fact, California issued
far more TIF debt than any other state, and the only
other states with more than $1 billion of TIF debt issued
are Illinois and Minnesota. A few states (including Iowa,
Maine, and Nebraska) have a substantial number of TIF
districts but a modest amount of TIF debt issuance.
Data source: This report, table 2, column 3.
Categories for MT, NH, SC, and TN are best
available estimates.
560–3,340
58–559
25–57
10–24
0–9
TOTAL
60
0
does not allow TIF
0
25,040
1,585
129
0
413
684
12
56
1,274
720
315
354
1
31
31
54
0
434
1,400
134
1,425
90
2010–2014
2
0
0
3,233
434
129
0
68
21
12
33
169
246
9
14
0
10
30
40
0
100
202
23
248
20
2005–2009
30
0
0
11,609
704
0
0
235
554
0
8
448
337
186
325
1
5
0
0
0
148
500
61
658
48
2000–2004
28
0
0
10,198
447
0
0
110
109
0
15
657
137
120
15
0
16
1
14
0
186
698
50
519
22
State
Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 31
Table 3
TIF Borrowing by State, 2000–2014 (millions of nominal dollars)
Source: Luby and Moldogazie (2014); personal communications.
TOTAL
60
0
does not allow TIF
0
25,040
1,585
129
0
413
684
12
56
1,274
720
315
354
1
31
31
54
0
434
1,400
134
1,425
90
2010–2014
2
0
0
3,233
434
129
0
68
21
12
33
169
246
9
14
0
10
30
40
0
100
202
23
248
20
2005–2009
30
0
0
11,609
704
0
0
235
554
0
8
448
337
186
325
1
5
0
0
0
148
500
61
658
48
2000–2004
28
0
0
10,198
447
0
0
110
109
0
15
657
137
120
15
0
16
1
14
0
186
698
50
519
22
State
Alabama
Alaska
Arizona
Arkansas
California
Colorado
Connecticut
Delaware
Florida
Georgia
Hawaii
Idaho
Illinois
Indiana
Iowa
Kansas
Kentucky
Louisiana
Maine
Maryland
Massachusetts
Michigan
Minnesota
Mississippi
Missouri
Montana
TOTAL
43
232
0
0
0
0
16
8
516
166
95
276
37
276
15
33
1,145
164
0
46
0
67
89
0
2010–2014
5
22
0
0
0
0
0
3
117
140
0
29
0
14
2
0
351
77
0
0
0
11
30
0
2005–2009
19
140
0
0
0
0
0
3
269
26
18
70
29
105
7
33
455
58
0
14
0
56
8
0
2000–2004
19
70
0
0
0
0
16
2
130
0
77
177
8
157
6
0
339
29
0
32
0
0
51
0
State
Nebraska
Nevada
New Hampshire
New Jersey
New Mexico
New York
North Carolina
North Dakota
Ohio
Oklahoma
Oregon
Pennsylvania
Rhode Island
South Carolina
South Dakota
Tennessee
Texas
Utah
Vermont
Virginia
Washington
West Virginia
Wisconsin
Wyoming
37,4665,84417,16714,455TOTAL
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 31
32 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Table 4
Determinants of TIF Adoption
How Has TIF Been Used?
Over the past quarter-century, scholars have con-
ducted numerous studies to better understand when
TIF is used. Table 4 provides some basic information
about nine empirical studies of the determinants of
TIF adoption. Each study predicts the probability of
TIF use as a function of an areas characteristics. The
six older studies use data from a particular state or
region, five of which are located in the Midwest and
one in Maine. The more recent studies use national
data from surveys of municipal officials. Eight of the
nine studies focus on TIF adoption at the municipal
or county level. Only Gibson (2003) predicts use at the
neighborhood level.
These empirical analyses focus on two fundamen-
tal questions. First, do municipal officials adopt TIF
because growth is slow and they wish to stimulate
growth or because growth is rapid and they wish to
capture growth in a tax base that would otherwise go
to overlying governments, such as counties, school
districts, or other special districts? Second, do com-
munities use TIF to gain a competitive advantage over
neighboring areas?
On the first question, the evidence is mixed. Ander-
sons evidence “strongly suggests that prior growth
is responsible for TIF adoption, while Man “finds no
empirical evidence to support the contention that
growing cities are more likely to adopt TIF” (Anderson
1990, 160; Man 1999a, 1151). Gibson (2003) finds that
moderately economically distressed neighborhoods,
which experience moderate growth, are most likely to
be included in TIF districts. There is little point in using
TIF in an area that is not growing at all, but municipal-
ities may also be reluctant to use TIF in an area that is
growing rapidly already.
Article Area Data
Time
Period
Dependent
Variable(s)
Reasons for Increases
in the Probability of TIF
Adoption
Notes
Anderson, John E. (1990) Michigan 255 cities
1985–
1986
Probability of TIF
adoption
City growth
TIF adoption and
property value
growth estimated
simultaneously
Man, Joyce Y. (1999) Indiana
150 cities with a population
above 2,500
1985–
1991
Probability of TIF
adoption
Fiscal stress, lower share
of property taxes, and if
neighboring areas adopt TIF
TIF adoption and
property value
growth estimated
simultaneously
LaPlante, Josephine M. (2001) Maine
86 larger municipalities
(42 of which adopted TIF)
1989–
1998
Probability of TIF
adoption at the time
analyses were done
Nonmunicipal tax burden,
business share of property tax,
and percentage elderly
Predictive discriminant
analyses used without
correction for
simultaneity
Gibson, Diane (2003) Chicago 866 census tracts
1990–
2000
Time until census
tract became part of
a TIF district
Neighborhood distress and the
presence of an Empowerment
Zone, but probability falls with
the tenure of alderman
Study finds that mod-
erately disadvantaged
neighborhoods are most
likely to get TIF
Byrne, Paul F. (2005)
Chicago Metropolitan
Area
255 municipalities 2000
Probability of TIF
adoption
Neighboring areas adopt TIF,
percent of overlap with school
district, and municipal tax rate
None
Mason, Susan, and Kenneth P. Thomas (2010) Missouri 171 cities
Spring
2008
Approval of a TIF and
approval of a retail TIF
Use other economic develop-
ment tools, and neighboring
areas adopt TIF
No correction
for simultaneity
Warner, Mildred E., and Lingwen Zheng (2013) United States
800 chief municipal
administrative officers
2004 and
2009
Use of business
development incen-
tives that reduce
costs to business
Accountability, competition, and
unemployment, but falls with
citizen opposition and low per
capita property taxes
Two other non-TIF
types of development
incentives also studied
Felix, R. Alison, and James R. Hines (2013) United States
1,022 chief municipal
development officers
1999
Use of TIF alone or
in combination with
other business devel-
opment incentives
Share of low-income residents,
proximity to state borders, and
political corruption
Poorest communities
less likely to use TIF
Greenbaum, Robert T., and Jim Landers (2014) United States
844 municipal and
county governments
2009 Use of TIF
Government size,
low-income residents,
and suburban location
Study finds significant
regional differences
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 33
Article Area Data
Time
Period
Dependent
Variable(s)
Reasons for Increases
in the Probability of TIF
Adoption
Notes
Anderson, John E. (1990) Michigan 255 cities
1985–
1986
Probability of TIF
adoption
City growth
TIF adoption and
property value
growth estimated
simultaneously
Man, Joyce Y. (1999) Indiana
150 cities with a population
above 2,500
1985–
1991
Probability of TIF
adoption
Fiscal stress, lower share
of property taxes, and if
neighboring areas adopt TIF
TIF adoption and
property value
growth estimated
simultaneously
LaPlante, Josephine M. (2001) Maine
86 larger municipalities
(42 of which adopted TIF)
1989–
1998
Probability of TIF
adoption at the time
analyses were done
Nonmunicipal tax burden,
business share of property tax,
and percentage elderly
Predictive discriminant
analyses used without
correction for
simultaneity
Gibson, Diane (2003) Chicago 866 census tracts
1990–
2000
Time until census
tract became part of
a TIF district
Neighborhood distress and the
presence of an Empowerment
Zone, but probability falls with
the tenure of alderman
Study finds that mod-
erately disadvantaged
neighborhoods are most
likely to get TIF
Byrne, Paul F. (2005)
Chicago Metropolitan
Area
255 municipalities 2000
Probability of TIF
adoption
Neighboring areas adopt TIF,
percent of overlap with school
district, and municipal tax rate
None
Mason, Susan, and Kenneth P. Thomas (2010) Missouri 171 cities
Spring
2008
Approval of a TIF and
approval of a retail TIF
Use other economic develop-
ment tools, and neighboring
areas adopt TIF
No correction
for simultaneity
Warner, Mildred E., and Lingwen Zheng (2013) United States
800 chief municipal
administrative officers
2004 and
2009
Use of business
development incen-
tives that reduce
costs to business
Accountability, competition, and
unemployment, but falls with
citizen opposition and low per
capita property taxes
Two other non-TIF
types of development
incentives also studied
Felix, R. Alison, and James R. Hines (2013) United States
1,022 chief municipal
development officers
1999
Use of TIF alone or
in combination with
other business devel-
opment incentives
Share of low-income residents,
proximity to state borders, and
political corruption
Poorest communities
less likely to use TIF
Greenbaum, Robert T., and Jim Landers (2014) United States
844 municipal and
county governments
2009 Use of TIF
Government size,
low-income residents,
and suburban location
Study finds significant
regional differences
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 33
34 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
If nonmunicipal governments, such as school districts,
are responsible for the majority of the property tax
burden in an area, a municipality-initiated TIF district
can capture tax revenue for economic development at
a relatively low cost to the municipality. For example,
suppose that 10 cents of each dollar paid in property
taxes goes to the municipality, 65 cents goes to the
school district, and 25 cents goes to the county or
other local governments, such as park and transpor-
tation districts. Municipalities might be more likely to
use TIF since they bear only a small share of the cost
for redirected property tax dollars. Anderson (1990,
161) studied this but found the proportion of the tax
rate attributed to the city government has no impact”
on TIF adoption, suggesting that towns do not act stra-
tegically to capture TIF revenue. LaPlante (2001, 91)
finds that “a town with a heavy municipal tax burden
is likely to embrace TIF,” but her results are difficult to
compare with Andersons (1990), as she did not control
simultaneously for the tax share of overlying govern-
ments. Both Byrne (2005) and Mason and Thomas
(2010) found that towns are more likely to adopt TIF
when their neighboring towns use it. This suggests
strategic, or at least competitive, behavior.
Studies that use survey data have the virtue of
covering a much broader geographic area, but survey
respondents answers may be subjective, and thus the
analyses may be less revealing compared to studies
using administrative data collected to implement or
monitor government programs. Warner and Zheng
(2013), Felix and Hines (2013), and Greenbaum and
Landers (2014) all find evidence that economic dis-
tress promotes the use of TIF. Warner and Zheng find
more use of TIF-type incentives when there is more
accountability for results, while Felix and Hines find
evidence that TIF is used to compete with neighboring
jurisdictions and is possibly associated with political
corruption. Greenbaum and Landers emphasize that
the determinants of TIF use in the north-central region
are somewhat different from factors in the rest of the
country. In particular, higher property taxes are associ-
ated with more TIF use in the north-central region, but
not in other regions.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 35
CHAPTER 5
Transparency: Intensive TIF Use in Chicago
Some have called for more transparent use of TIF revenues.
Once a municipality establishes a TIF district and begins to
receive revenues and make expenditures, it can account for
them separately—and sometimes obscurely—compared to
other governmental funds. Some argue that municipalities
could achieve transparency by including TIF-funded activi-
ties as part of a city’s regular operating budget. Cities could
also document property tax dollars from TIF districts in
capital plans and in regular city financial reports.
Morgan Station in Chicago, funded almost
fully through TIF, accelerated the redevel-
opment of the area. Photo: Steven Vance/
Flickr CC BY-NC-SA 2.0.
36 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Background
Chicago has used TIF since the late 1980s, and
the lack of TIF transparency has been a particu-
larly salient issue there (Reingold 2001). By 1997,
Chicago had 41 TIF districts, and TIF use was rapidly
expanding (Youngman 2016). By the mid-2000s, TIF
use in Chicago was extremely controversial (Quigley
2007), and that controversy continues to the pres-
ent (Youngman 2016).
Chicago is worthy of special focus because of its
extensive and controversial use of TIF. By 2014—
after years of municipal fiscal distress—Chicago
used TIF more than any big city in the United States.
As shown in table 5, Chicago had as many TIF
districts (149) as the other nine largest U.S. cities
combined. In 2015 alone, Chicago TIFs collected
about $461 million in property tax revenues (Office
of the Cook County Clerk 2016).
More than $4.5 million in TIF funds were used to rebuild Cermak
Station in Chicago adjacent to the McCormick Place Convention
Center. Photo: Steven Vance/Flickr CC BY-NC-SA 2.0.
In August 2015, the Governmental Accounting Standards
Board (GASB) issued Statement No. 77 (GASB 77). The new
policy requires governments to disclose the amount of
tax revenues forgone through tax abatements, including
at least some of those made through TIF (Knezevic 2017),
for reporting periods that begin after December 15, 2015.
GASB establishes accounting and financial reporting
standards for U.S. governments that follow Generally
Accepted Accounting Principles (GAAP). GASB periodically
issues statements about how particular accounting issues
should be dealt with in government financial reports.
GASB 77’s potential to increase TIF transparency is
unclear. Because TIF, as generally implemented, does
GASB 77 AND TIF
not reduce tax payments but rather redirects the
expenditure of public funds, its status as a tax
abatement is sometimes unclear and disputed
(LeRoy 2017). Also, GASB 77 allows individual
governments discretion to disclose abatements
either individually or in aggregate, and aggregated
disclosure is less likely to provide information about
individual TIF districts within a government.
Careful analysis of GASB 77’s impact on financial
reporting probably won’t be available until at least
late 2018. For many governments, the first required
disclosure involved a fiscal year that began in the
calendar year 2016 and ended in the calendar year
2017, and financial reports generally do not appear
until several months after the fiscal year ends.
36 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Table 5
Population and TIF Use in Largest U.S. Cities
Source: U.S. Census Bureau; city websites.
City
Population,
2016
(in millions)
Districts, 2017
(except where noted)
New York, NY 8.54 0
Phoenix, AZ 1.62 0
Philadelphia, PA 1.57 13 (2013)
San Diego, CA 1.40
14
(in flux due to changes in
California law)
Dallas, TX 1.32 18
San Antonio, TX 1.49 19
San Jose, CA 1.02
21
(in flux due to changes in
California law)
Los Angeles, CA 3.98
24
(in flux due to changes in
California law)
Houston, TX 2.30 27
Chicago, IL 2.70 149
Total TIF Districts 285
Many aspects of TIF use in Chicago have been contro-
versial, but the central theme of these controversies
has revolved around the questions of who gets to decide
about the use of property tax dollars and how Chicagos
city government tracks and reports the collection and
dispersal of TIF tax dollars.
Spending TIF district dollars is fundamentally different
from other government spending. TIF dollars are raised
by a general property tax but must be spent to benefit
economic development in designated areas. In most
cases, TIF revenues derive from taxes levied by all over-
lying governments, such as counties, school districts, or
other special districts. Spending of TIF funds, unlike other
earmarked revenues, is not authorized, appropriated,
accounted for, or voted on during the normal budget cycle
of any elected government. Once a TIF district is created,
funds generated by the district do not compete with
non-TIF district priorities. Furthermore, TIF projects often
combine resources of private, and sometimes for-profit,
institutions with public money. Thus, TIF districts often
persist for decades without being subject to ordinary
democratic controls.
These sets of circumstances suggest that TIF districts
should be created only after careful study, deliberation,
and debate. Once created, TIF district activities should be
documented carefully and monitored by local government
officials to assure that they fulfill their stated missions.
The appendix table (p. 59) lists some of the conditions
mandated by state laws in order to create a TIF district.
Most states require a detailed application and public
hearings to solicit citizen input. State review of the appli-
cation is common, and usually the governing body of the
city must take a formal vote to approve the project.
While many states mandate well-articulated procedures
for creating TIF districts, state laws often require little
reporting or monitoring of TIF districts once they are
established. Without reporting, there can be little over-
sight, increasing the potential for misallocation—or even
abuse—of TIF spending. Because of this, demands for
TIF transparency have been loud and sometimes strident.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 37
38 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
One particularly persistent reporter, Ben Joravsky,
published dozens of mostly critical articles in the
Chicago Reader, a local newspaper, documenting the
lack of transparency in TIF and the frequency of polit-
ically influenced decision making in Chicago. Joravsky
alleged that then-Mayor Richard Daley used TIF dollars
as a shadow budget, which could be allocated with
minimal oversight from the elected city council or the
general public.
Reform Efforts
Joravskys reporting and some academic studies stim-
ulated additional interest in TIF, and in 2007, then-Cook
County Commissioner (and later U.S. Representative)
Mike Quigley published a report that found
[t]he near-total lack of public information readily
available on Chicagos TIFs is, in a word, inexcus-
able. Reams of documentation are produced—with
taxpayer dollars—every time a TIF is proposed
or created. Redevelopment agreements . . . [and]
compliance reports are submitted to the Comptrol-
ler annually. All . . . are produced electronically. Not
a single one is available from the City’s website.
(Quigley 2007, 41)
As pressure for reform grew, Mayor Rahm Emanuel
responded in 2011, just three days after his inaugura-
tion, by announcing the TIF Reform Task Force, charged
with recommending concrete steps for increasing TIF
transparency. Three months later, the task force issued
a report that proclaimed:
Information about TIF districts . . . has been limit-
ed since TIF was first used in 1983. However, more
comprehensive information . . . has been available
. . . since City Council passed the TIF Sunshine Ordi-
nance in 2009. The . . . website includes:
“Redevelopment plans and approval ordinan-
ces . . . [b]asic annual financial reports for each
TIF district . . . web pages for every TIF district
aggregating relevant information . . . [r]edevel-
opment agreements (RDAs) for private projects
. . . [t]hree-year district-level projections about
collections.
Although there has been a significant increase in
the amount of publicly available TIF information in
recent years, there is significant room to improve.
(City of Chicago, TIF Reform Panel 2011, 32)
To increase transparency, the task force recommended
that Chicago develop a multiyear capital budget incor-
porating TIF district spending and submit this capital
budget to the city council for consideration. The task
force further stated that TIF resources should undergo
the same scrutiny as other resources, and it recom-
mended a number of transparency measures, including
public disclosure of all intergovernmental agreements
related to TIF and publication on the city’s website of
the newly created capital budget as well as TIF district
and project data to track performance.
As of March 2018, the City of Chicago has an open data
portal with extensive information about TIF districts
and the projects they house (City of Chicago 2018).
The website contains a map of each TIF district with
its boundaries overlaid on a map of city streets. The
map indicates each project within the TIF district and
specifies redevelopment agreements and total TIF and
non-TIF planned investments. Figure 5 shows, for ex-
ample, the Greater Southwest Industrial Corridor (East)
TIF district on Chicagos southwest side. This district
encompasses portions of several communities, includ-
ing the predominantly low-income, African American
communities of Ashburn and Auburn-Gresham. The
website says that the TIF district is intended to encour-
age land uses that strengthen the appeal of the area
for industrial, commercial, institutional, and residential
uses. A few specific targeted projects include the
redevelopment of an abandoned theater and aban-
doned railroad right-of-way.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 39
Figure 5
Greater Southwest Industrial Corridor (East) TIF District
Source: City of Chicago, Department of Planning and Development (2018).
According to Chicagos 2014 annual report, the TIF
district housed a single redevelopment project, which
was designed to facilitate cleanup and remediation
of a 62-acre industrial site. The project also includ-
ed construction of a 660,000-square-foot industrial
space for StyleMaster and other tenants. A direct link
from Chicagos mapping portal allows users to access
the associated 111-page redevelopment agreement,
amendments to that agreement, a Department of
Planning and Development staff report on the project,
and several other related documents. These reports
detail the legal basis for the project, projected costs,
and time lines. As of early 2017, total projected costs
were about $28 million, split about evenly between
public and private investments.
Chicagos TIF portal also provides separate access
to data about beginning and ending balances, reve-
nues, and expenditures in the TIF district. The Greater
Southwest Industrial Corridor (East) began in 2001
with balances of about $320,000 and ended in 2014
with balances of $2.5 million. In 2014, revenues for
40 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Concern about transparency in the use of
TIF extends beyond Chicago.
this TIF district included about $9,000 of interest and
about $500,000 of property tax revenues; expenditures
that year totaled $1.2 million, and the vast majority was
spent on site assembly and preparation ($370,000) and
public improvements ($733,000).
Because property taxes in Illinois are assessed, billed,
and collected at the county level, counties are intri-
cately involved in the administration of TIF districts.
The Cook County Clerk has a separate county-level
website with additional information about each TIF
district, including maps and lists of the total and frozen
assessed value and revenue distribution for each dis-
trict. Additionally, information about property tax rev-
enue that goes to TIF districts has been added to Cook
County tax bills sent to owners of real estate parcels.
Even though information about TIF districts in Chicago
and Cook County is significantly more available than it
was in 2011 when Mayor Emanuels task force issued
its report, there continues to be significant vocal and
organized opposition to Cook County’s use of TIF, such
as from the TIF Illumination Project.
More data about TIF is unquestionably available in
Chicago today, but some of the specific recommenda-
tions of Mayor Emanuels 2011 task force have not been
fully implemented and monitored. Recommendations
included, for example, formally establishing the citys
TIF goals and metrics to monitor the performance of TIF
districts. The City of Chicago Department of Planning
and Development, however, failed to produce documen-
tation of formal implementation or monitoring based on
these recommendations after repeated inquiries.
Concern about transparency in the use of TIF extends
beyond Chicago. In an analysis looking at national
patterns of TIF use, Kirth and Baxandall (2011, 2) argue
that “TIF often lacks transparency.They note that
some states do not publish TIF budgets for public
review at all. The authors further express concern
that in some states TIF money can be used as a
slush fund” for entrenched local officials and that
recipients of aid through TIF are not always held
accountable for results.
Despite continued controversy over the use of
conventionalTIF districts, Illinois state legislators
authorized Chicago to establish a new kind of TIF dis-
trict in June 2016. These transit TIFs” were designed
to help the city designate a source of matching funds
to secure $800 million in federal funding to improve
its commuter-rail system. The legislation allows the
city to create long, narrow TIF districts within a half-
mile radius of a rail station, irrespective of the usual
blight requirement. Unlike conventional TIF districts,
which generally capture all incremental property tax
revenue on real estate, the transit TIF does not cap-
ture revenue accruing to the City of Chicago School
District. Other overlying governments, such as the
county or park district, will give up only 20 percent
of the revenue they otherwise would have received
from the increment. Also, transit TIF districts can last
35 years, rather than the 23-year duration of most
conventional TIF districts (Vance 2016).
Chicagos experience demonstrates both the allure
of TIF and the potential for governmental misuse and
public mistrust of it. Although the city and county
government reforms have increased accountability
and transparency, TIF remains a very controversial
tool, especially as its uses continue to evolve. This
suggests that transparency and monitoring efforts
should continue and should themselves be evaluated
on a regular basis.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 41
CHAPTER 6
TIF Reversal: Californias Story
California was the first state to make extensive use of tax
increment financing—and recently became the first state
to reverse course and drastically reduce its use of TIF.
California may thus provide an instructive case study for
other states wishing to avoid some of the pitfalls of TIF.
The Hammer Theatre, a venue for perfor-
mances and cultural activities, is owned
by the city and operated by San Jose
State University. It was funded in large
part by the San Jose Redevelopment
Agency. Photo: Allie_Caulfield/Flickr CC
BY 2.0.
42 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
History
California began using TIF in the early 1950s and was
one of the heaviest users outside of the Midwest re-
gion in the last several decades. California TIF districts
are housed in redevelopment areas (RDAs) and, by
2008, California had over 400 RDAs with more than
$10 billion in annual revenue, $28 billion in debt, and
more than $674 billion in aggregate assessed values
(Swenson 2015).
Californias legal structure for TIF had been in place for
decades prior to the passage of Proposition 13 in 1978,
which fundamentally changed the California property
tax system by both limiting the property tax rate to 1
percent of market value and by dramatically limiting
the rate at which real estate assessments could rise,
except in the event of ownership transfers. According
to Lefcoe and Swenson,
Proposition 13 cut local government property tax
revenues in half and diminished school funding by
60 percent. . . . Redevelopment in California would
never have become so widespread but for Proposi-
tion 13. Desperate for replacement revenues, cities
(and a few counties) saw an opportunity to fill their
depleted property tax coffers by culling property
taxes from other taxing entities. (2014, 723)
TIF allowed California general purpose governments—
mostly cities, but also some counties—to garner
property tax revenues that otherwise would have gone
to school districts and other overlying governments.
The number of redevelopment agencies—and cor-
responding TIF districts—exploded in the 1970s and
1980s as local governments used every conceivable
tool to overcome the revenue shortfalls resulting from
Proposition 13. The state government was constitu-
tionally obligated to make up at least some of school
districts lost property tax revenues, so this prolifera-
tion of TIF districts also imposed a fiscal burden at the
state level.
Limitations
In the years after the passage of Proposition 13, the
California legislature enacted rules to restrain and
restrict the use of TIF, including a strict definition of
blight required for the establishment of a TIF district.
The rules required that 20 percent of overlying govern-
ments contributions to TIF revenue be passed back
to those governments. Despite these requirements,
TIF continued to drain a large share of revenues from
school districts and other overlying governments. A
legal battle ensued, and the California state govern-
ment attempted to redirect funds from RDAs. This was
finally settled in 2010, when a ballot initiative called
Proposition 22 passed, preventing the state government
from raiding RDA funds and putting increased financial
pressure on the state. According to Lefcoe and Swenson
(2014, 732), the passage of Proposition 22 “left the per-
manent dissolution of redevelopment as the states only
remaining option for re-directing property taxes away
from RDAs to more urgent public needs.
Like most states, California faced intense fiscal pres-
sure during and after the Great Recession, which began
in 2008. In this environment, the dissolution of RDAs
presented the state with an attractive potential fiscal
windfall. During the legislative debate, Governor Jerry
Brown said the state would get $1.7 billion immediately
and $400 million in each following fiscal year if RDAs
were abolished (Herr, Clark, and Levin 2012).
Despite its heavy investment in TIF, the California
legislature ultimately passed legislation in 2010,
known locally as AB-26, which dissolved the RDAs that
housed TIF districts under California law (Lefoce and
Swenson 2014). Passage of AB-26, companion legisla-
tion AB-27, and subsequent court rulings would allow
local governments to keep RDAs and TIF districts in
existence—for a price. Californias local governments,
however, have not pursued this or other options to con-
tinue the use of TIF. Given that Californias current
requirements for the use of TIF include affordable
housing mandates and prohibit capturing revenues
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 43
Swenson concludes that Californias decision to end
TIF may have been wise because evidence showed
that TIF did not stimulate economic development and
significantly diverted resources from both the state and
overlying local governments. The use of California TIF
also did not conform to the “but for” requirement.
In October 2015, the California legislature approved
and Governor Brown signed AB-2 (California Legislative
Information 2015), which once again gave local gov-
ernments the authority to create TIF districts in some
circumstances. Compared to previous California TIF
legislation, AB-2 imposed many limits on TIF-creating
governments. Most importantly:
TIF districts are restricted to low-income or
high-crime areas;
school entities are prohibited from participating;
other overlying governments (nonschool) must
consent to use their tax revenues for the TIF;
extensive reporting and transparency provisions
are required;
extensive public input is required, including
provisions under which a popular vote could
prevent further action on the plan;
twenty-five percent of property tax increment
revenues must be used to increase, improve, and
preserve affordable housing; and
issuance of bonds by TIF districts now requires
55 percent voter approval. (League of California
Cities 2016)
The above conditions appear to restrict the use of TIF
in California to a narrow set of circumstances and thus
prevent future overuse or abuse. It should be noted,
however, that there is a tendency for TIF legislation to
be modified gradually to allow for more expansive uses.
In fact, AB-2 was soon modified by legislation that
took effect January 1, 2017 (Torres 2016). While these
changes seem to be innocuous, vigilance will be
required to assure that TIF legislation serves its
stated purpose.
from overlying governments, such as schools or special
districts, TIF has been rendered unattractive to local gov-
ernments compared to other economic development tools.
AB-26 set up an extensive and careful protocol to wind
down existing RDAs and make payments to “enforce
obligations previously made by RDAs. Revenue in
excess of the amount needed to cover these obligations
was overseen by the State Department of Finance Tax
and returned to overlying governments (Herr, Clark, and
Levin 2012).
Results
Swenson (2015) asks whether Californias defunct TIF
program was successful. This study provides an excellent
follow-up to Dardias (1998) very early study of a similar
question. Dardia found that, although Californian TIF
districts grew faster than his comparison group, the
benefits ultimately did not justify the costs because
public revenues diverted to economic development
were less than the revenues eventually generated by
increased property values.
Swenson (2015) developed a unique data set that allowed
precise geographic comparisons. Using this information,
Swenson compared economic activity in California RDAs
to adjacent areas without RDAs. He showed that, during
the 1980s, census tracts adjacent to RDAs had econom-
ic growth rates very similar to those that would later be
within the RDA. Using appropriate statistical methods
and controls, Swenson studied whether the formation of
the RDA had caused a relative improvement in economic
growth in the tracts housed within RDAs. He concluded,
The results show that in the 1990s there was little
measurable impact of RDAs on RDA area employment,
poverty rates, family incomes, rental vacancy rates,
and average residential rental rates. There was also
little measurable business growth in such areas during
the 2000–2009 decade in terms of job creation or busi-
ness revenues. (2015, 211)
44 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
CHAPTER 7
Efficacy in Economic Development
As previously discussed, TIF should promote economic
development. In particular, TIF is designed to promote real
estate investments that raise the market and assessed
values of real estate parcels in a given area. So, does TIF
work? Does the establishment of a TIF district result in
higher real estate value beyond increases that would have
occurred without the TIF designation?
In one sense, the answer should almost certainly be yes,
if all stakeholders strictly adhered to the legal dictates of
TIF. Generally, the relevant legislation requires that TIF can
be used only if the planned development would not have
occurred “but for” the TIF district. Yet, TIF often fails in both
obvious and subtle ways. Flaws in TIF result more often
from poor execution than from conceptual design.
One study found that TIF designation had
no impact on employment, establishment
counts, or building permits in Chicago.
Photo: Dan Perry/Flickr CC BY 2.0.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 45
Assessing TIFs Successes
and Failures
Compared to other methods of public funding to pro-
mote economic development, TIF has several virtues.
First, TIF funding is designed so that, if used as in-
tended, economic development funds will not displace
other public spending because the revenue generated
by TIF would not have been available “but for that TIF.
In contrast, some government programs designed to
stimulate economic development, such as advertising
campaigns, require up-front expenditures despite
uncertain returns. Unlike such appropriated economic
development expenditures, TIF design allows expen-
ditures of public funds only out of revenues that are
themselves the product of increases in the tax base.
Second, TIF provides benefits to private developers
only when the tax base appreciates, so private devel-
opers only receive revenue derived from appreciation
that otherwise would not have occurred in the absence
of their investment. This makes it difficult for private
developers to get something for nothing, as long as the
TIF is appropriately designed.
Despite TIF’s conceptual strengths, it remains vulner-
able to abuse and often falls short in execution. First,
TIF can fail simply if planned developments do not
materialize. Generally, TIF districts are established
based on a plan that may specify both public and
private investments. The public investment sometimes
precedes the private investment and may be funded
with public debt to be serviced by a revenue stream
from taxes on the increment. If the public investment
occurs but the planned private investment does not
follow, or if it follows too slowly, revenue to service
the bonds may be insufficient, and the government
could either default on the TIF debt or have to service
it through other revenues. We know that complete
failures of this type are relatively rare, as defaults on
TIF debt are quite rare (Lemov 2010; Moody’s Inves-
tor Service 2012). However, it is not uncommon for
public or private investment to lag, even years after
a TIF district is initiated, or drastically underperform
relative to the amount specified in the TIF plan.
A second potential hazard in the use of TIF is
caused by a design flaw in many states TIF stat-
utes discussed in chapter 2. In a number of states,
TIF statutes direct to the TIF district all incremental
property tax revenues generated by appreciation
above the frozen base value. This overestimates the
fiscal benefit of TIF, as some appreciation of land and
structures occurs in most areas, even in the absence
of investment. Appreciation could result either from
inflation or because regional growth raises demand
for all fixed assets. Crediting TIF districts with reve-
nue they did not earn may be especially problematic
because part of the unearned TIF revenue would oth-
erwise have been directed to overlying governments,
like school districts, in the absence of TIF. These
governments typically have little say in the establish-
ment of TIF districts. Municipalities that establish
TIF may regard these unearned funds as a windfall
and tend to use TIF even when the total costs are less
than the benefits.
A third potential pitfall for TIF is that, even though
development may occur within the district, the devel-
opment may not be worth the costs that it imposes
on the community. For example, a TIF district might
generate a new commercial business—for instance, a
theater—that would not have been built “but for” the
TIF district. The theater may even generate suffi-
cient tax revenues to pay for the public investments
that were necessary to attract private investments.
Despite this fiscal success, the TIF district may fail if
the new development imposes negative externalities
like traffic, crime, or noise pollution that lowers the
value of nearby houses or businesses.
46 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
A fourth, subtler, and more common problem is when
a TIF district fails to adhere strictly to the “but for”
requirement. Adherence requires a prediction about
what would happen in the absence of TIF. Thus, strictly
speaking, we can never know with certainty whether a
TIF district adhered to the “but for requirement.
Although state statutes and regulations generally
require specific criteria that must be documented prior
to the establishment of a TIF district, these criteria
are vague enough that almost any project with strong
political support can satisfy the “but for” requirement.
In particular, TIF projects may be approved even
though the development that occurs in the TIF district
is offset by a loss of similar development in a nearby
location, would likely have occurred at the location
of the TIF district at a later time, or is offset by the
loss of a different but similarly valued development
that would have occurred even if the TIF project had
not been approved. Wisconsins TIF manual has a
section devoted to the “but for” clause. It advises
local officials that the “but for clause requires that
“the proposed development would not happen unless
financial support is available from TIF” (Wisconsin
Department of Revenue 2017a, chapter 5.1).
Research suggests that TIF often displaces economic activity that would have happened anyway in economically vibrant areas.
In Kansas City, Missouri, eight times as many TIF deals were approved in low-poverty areas such as Country Club Plaza (left) than
in areas like East Kansas City (right), with poverty rates above 30 percent despite the fact that high poverty often impedes economic
activity. Photo: Eric Bowers.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 47
Although state statutes and regulations
generally require specific criteria that must
be documented prior to the establishment
of a TIF district, these criteria are vague
enough that almost any project with
strong political support can satisfy the
“but for” requirement.
This interpretation of “but for” might allow TIF use even
when it would displace other potential development;
however, the Wisconsin law also requires that:
1. the economic benefits of the TIF district compen-
sate for the cost of improvements; and
2. the anticipated tax increments outweigh the costs
to overlapping taxing districts.
These criteria are laudable. If interpreted strictly, crite-
rion 1 would require any development displaced by the
TIF district to count as a cost of the TIF project. Criterion
2 would require that future gains offset costs to over-
lapping taxing districts. The challenge for Wisconsin
and other states is to adhere strictly to these criteria
during implementation.
Effects of TIF Adoption on
Economic Activity
As discussed, TIF has both conceptual strengths and
potential weaknesses. Numerous empirical studies have
attempted to sort this out and determine whether, on
average, TIF delivers what it promises. Like any empir-
ical study of a policy regime, evaluation requires the
analyst to separate the data into “treated” and “control
areas. Treated areas receive TIF districts, while control
areas do not. As TIF treatments cannot be assigned
randomly, the main empirical challenge is to find control
areas that are similar to areas that receive TIF, so that
data from control areas might predict what would have
occurred in the treated areas in TIF’s absence. In es-
sence, this measure is designed to answer the question
of whether the “but for criterion has been met. Studies
must also wrestle with the question of whether the ob-
served development in the TIF district might have come
at the expense of development that otherwise would
have occurred in nearby venues.
Table 6 (p.48) provides some basic information
about 31 empirical studies, listed in chronological
order by publication date, that have attempted to
answer these questions in a methodical way. All the
studies use some measure of economic activity as
the variable to be explained—often a dependent
variable in a regression equation—and all include an
independent variable that measures TIF use or TIF
intensity. Perhaps unsurprisingly, the studies draw
primarily from data in Midwestern (or north-central)
states where TIF is most widely used. Twenty-two of
the studies use data from Illinois, Indiana, Michigan,
Minnesota, or Wisconsin. California and Texas have
two studies each; Iowa, Florida, Georgia, Maryland,
and Missouri each have one.
The dependent (or outcome) variables include
employment, retail sales, assessed values, growth
in median house value, median household income,
and value of building permits, among others.
Many studies report results about more than
one dependent variable.
48 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Article City, State, or Region Data Time Dependent Variable(s) Finding(s) Notes
Summary
Finding
Wassmer, Robert W. (1994) Detroit Metropolitan Area 25 cities 1947–1987 Employment or retail sales
TIF increased retail employment, but had no significant effect
on retail sales or service receipts.
Controls for a number of other economic development incentives Positive
Dardia, Michael (1998) California
47,000 parcels in 38
redevelopment projects and
matched-pair areas
1978–1996 Assessed values
TIF did not generate enough extra tax revenue to compensate
overlying governments for loss of revenue during TIF period.
Matched-pair methodology Negative
Man, Joyce Y., and Mark S. Rosentraub
(1998)
Indiana 151 cities 1990
Real growth in value of
median valued house
TIF increased median owner-occupied housing value by 11.4 %. TIF adoption treated as endogenous Positive
Man, Joyce Y. (1999b) Indiana
53 cities with populations
greater than 10,000
1985–1992 Employment
Cities with TIF have about 4.5% more jobs than cities without TIF. TIF adoption treated as exogenous Positive
Dye, Richard F., and David F. Merriman
(2000)
Chicago Metropolitan Area 235 municipalities 1980–1995
Growth in municipal property
value, 1992–1995
Cities that adopt TIF grow between 0.78% and
2.18% slower than those that do not.
Revenue shifting not a determinant of TIF adoption Negative
Wassmer, Robert W., and
John E. Anderson (2001)
Detroit Metropolitan Area 112 municipalities 19771992 Commercial property value
TIF increased commercial property value by 12%. TIF adoption treated as endogenous Positive
Kriz, Kenneth A. (2001) Minneapolis, MN
Simulated data based on
observed values
Parameters based
on data available
around 2000
Net present value (NPV)
of TIF project
The net present value of a typical TIF district will be
negative under most plausible assumptions.
Simulation results limited to the financial effects of TIF Negative
Dye, Richard F., and David F. Merriman
(2003)
Illinois 1,242 municipalities 1980–1998
Growth in non-TIF municipal
property value, 1995–1998
Non-TIF municipal property values grow slower in cities with TIF.
Similar negative results with sample of Chicago Metropolitan Area
communities; TIF adoption estimated simultaneously
Negative
Weber, Rachel, Saurav Dev Bhatta, and
David Merriman (2003)
Chicago, IL
154 sales of vacant industrial
parcels
1999–2002 Natural log of parcel price
Value of parcels in industrial TIF districts
fall by 40% to 66%.
Value of parcels in mixed-use TIF rise by 15% to 115%.
TIF adoption estimated simultaneously;
similar results obtained with much larger sample of
industrial parcels with structures
Mixed
Rogers, Cynthia L., and Jill L. Tao (2004) Florida 31 small cities 1980–1990
Population, unemployment-
to-population ratio, median
property value, and median
household income
TIF had no significant effect on any of the dependent variables.
Considers both TIF and enterprise zones;
quasi-experimental methods and regression analyses used
Neutral
Ingraham, Allan T., Hal J. Singer, and
Thomas G. Thibodeau (2005)
Dallas, TX
Case study of a proposed retail
TIF district
1990–2003
Share of newly TIF-generated
retail sales that cannibalize
sales of neighbors
Less than 34% of growth in TIF cannibalizes
non-TIF development.
Argues that Dallas benefits whenever cannibalization
rate is less than 93%
Positive
Carroll, Deborah A., and Robert J. Eger
(2006)
Milwaukee, WI 17 aldermanic districts 1993–2000
Real assessed property value
within aldermanic district
Each dollar of TIF financing generates a $3.50 increase
in property value.
TIF adoption not estimated simultaneously Positive
Byrne, Paul F. (2006) Chicago Metropolitan Area
89 TIF districts in
67 municipalities
1990–1993
Annualized property value
growth
Industrial, blighted, and centrally located TIF districts grow
faster than the municipalities that house them.
Lagged demographic independent variables used to
reduce endogeneity concerns
Positive
Smith, Brent C. (2006) Chicago, IL 36,158 multifamily units 1992–2000
Natural log of sale price
per square foot
Price of units within a TIF district grew slightly faster
than those outside TIF districts.
TIF adoption not estimated simultaneously Positive
Weber, Rachel, Saurav Dev Bhatta, and
David Merriman (2007)
Chicago, IL
5,852 single-family homes
that sold more than once
1993–1999
Sale price of single-family
homes sold more than once
during the time period
Houses near mixed-use TIF districts appreciated faster than those
farther away, but units near industrial or commercial TIF districts
appreciated slower.
Three sets of data used; results do not support hypothesis Mixed
Table 6
Empirical Studies of Effect of TIF on Economic Activity
48 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 49
Article City, State, or Region Data Time Dependent Variable(s) Finding(s) Notes
Summary
Finding
Wassmer, Robert W. (1994) Detroit Metropolitan Area 25 cities 1947–1987 Employment or retail sales
TIF increased retail employment, but had no significant effect
on retail sales or service receipts.
Controls for a number of other economic development incentives Positive
Dardia, Michael (1998) California
47,000 parcels in 38
redevelopment projects and
matched-pair areas
1978–1996 Assessed values
TIF did not generate enough extra tax revenue to compensate
overlying governments for loss of revenue during TIF period.
Matched-pair methodology Negative
Man, Joyce Y., and Mark S. Rosentraub
(1998)
Indiana 151 cities 1990
Real growth in value of
median valued house
TIF increased median owner-occupied housing value by 11.4 %. TIF adoption treated as endogenous Positive
Man, Joyce Y. (1999b) Indiana
53 cities with populations
greater than 10,000
1985–1992 Employment
Cities with TIF have about 4.5% more jobs than cities without TIF. TIF adoption treated as exogenous Positive
Dye, Richard F., and David F. Merriman
(2000)
Chicago Metropolitan Area 235 municipalities 1980–1995
Growth in municipal property
value, 1992–1995
Cities that adopt TIF grow between 0.78% and
2.18% slower than those that do not.
Revenue shifting not a determinant of TIF adoption Negative
Wassmer, Robert W., and
John E. Anderson (2001)
Detroit Metropolitan Area 112 municipalities 19771992 Commercial property value
TIF increased commercial property value by 12%. TIF adoption treated as endogenous Positive
Kriz, Kenneth A. (2001) Minneapolis, MN
Simulated data based on
observed values
Parameters based
on data available
around 2000
Net present value (NPV)
of TIF project
The net present value of a typical TIF district will be
negative under most plausible assumptions.
Simulation results limited to the financial effects of TIF Negative
Dye, Richard F., and David F. Merriman
(2003)
Illinois 1,242 municipalities 1980–1998
Growth in non-TIF municipal
property value, 1995–1998
Non-TIF municipal property values grow slower in cities with TIF.
Similar negative results with sample of Chicago Metropolitan Area
communities; TIF adoption estimated simultaneously
Negative
Weber, Rachel, Saurav Dev Bhatta, and
David Merriman (2003)
Chicago, IL
154 sales of vacant industrial
parcels
1999–2002 Natural log of parcel price
Value of parcels in industrial TIF districts
fall by 40% to 66%.
Value of parcels in mixed-use TIF rise by 15% to 115%.
TIF adoption estimated simultaneously;
similar results obtained with much larger sample of
industrial parcels with structures
Mixed
Rogers, Cynthia L., and Jill L. Tao (2004) Florida 31 small cities 1980–1990
Population, unemployment-
to-population ratio, median
property value, and median
household income
TIF had no significant effect on any of the dependent variables.
Considers both TIF and enterprise zones;
quasi-experimental methods and regression analyses used
Neutral
Ingraham, Allan T., Hal J. Singer, and
Thomas G. Thibodeau (2005)
Dallas, TX
Case study of a proposed retail
TIF district
1990–2003
Share of newly TIF-generated
retail sales that cannibalize
sales of neighbors
Less than 34% of growth in TIF cannibalizes
non-TIF development.
Argues that Dallas benefits whenever cannibalization
rate is less than 93%
Positive
Carroll, Deborah A., and Robert J. Eger
(2006)
Milwaukee, WI 17 aldermanic districts 1993–2000
Real assessed property value
within aldermanic district
Each dollar of TIF financing generates a $3.50 increase
in property value.
TIF adoption not estimated simultaneously Positive
Byrne, Paul F. (2006) Chicago Metropolitan Area
89 TIF districts in
67 municipalities
1990–1993
Annualized property value
growth
Industrial, blighted, and centrally located TIF districts grow
faster than the municipalities that house them.
Lagged demographic independent variables used to
reduce endogeneity concerns
Positive
Smith, Brent C. (2006) Chicago, IL 36,158 multifamily units 1992–2000
Natural log of sale price
per square foot
Price of units within a TIF district grew slightly faster
than those outside TIF districts.
TIF adoption not estimated simultaneously Positive
Weber, Rachel, Saurav Dev Bhatta, and
David Merriman (2007)
Chicago, IL
5,852 single-family homes
that sold more than once
1993–1999
Sale price of single-family
homes sold more than once
during the time period
Houses near mixed-use TIF districts appreciated faster than those
farther away, but units near industrial or commercial TIF districts
appreciated slower.
Three sets of data used; results do not support hypothesis Mixed
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 49
50 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Article City, State, or Region Data Time Dependent Variable(s) Finding(s) Notes
Summary
Finding
Carroll, Deborah A. (2008) Milwaukee, WI 12,169 business parcels 1980–1999 Real assessed value Business parcels located in TIF districts grow faster. TIF adoption treated as endogenous Positive
Smith, Brent C. (2009) Chicago, IL
4,022 commercial
property sales
1992 and 2000 Commercial property values
Commercial property values appreciate faster in TIF districts. TIF adoption treated as endogenous Positive
Immergluck, Dan (2009) Atlanta, GA
25,999 house sales near the
BeltLine TIF district
2003–2005 Log of sale price
Announcement of the TIF district caused prices to increase
substantially near some parts of the TIF district.
Effects varied with geography; negative effects in some areas Positive
Byrne, Paul F. (2010) Illinois
1,449 observations in a panel
of municipalities
1980–1999 Employment
On average, TIF has no effect on employment, but industrial TIF
increases employment.
Some controls for endogeneity Neutral
Skidmore, Mark, and Russ Kashian
(2010)
Wisconsin 537 municipalities 1990–2003 Property tax rates
With TIF in place, the property tax rate of nonmunicipal governments
rises, but the property tax rate of municipal governments falls.
Lagged control variables reduce concerns about endogeneity Mixed
Merriman, David F., Mark L. Skidmore,
and Russ D. Kashian (2011)
Wisconsin All municipalities 1990–2003
Real per capita value of
real estate
TIF does not increase in total, residential, or manufacturing property
values, but may increase commercial property values.
Panel data reduce concerns about endogeneity Neutral
Bossard, Jennifer A. (2011) Minnesota
Panel of 334–421 school
districts
1992–2007
Non-TIF district property value
growth for school districts
Increases in TIF intensity result in more rapid growth.
TIF intensity too low to maximize non-TIF school district
property value growth
Positive
Giradi, Anthony G. (2013) Iowa All counties 20022012
Standardized employment
growth and wage growth
TIF had no impact on wage or employment growth.
Actual employment and wages compared to predicted level;
controlling for industrial composition
Neutral
Lester, T. William (2014) Chicago, IL
1,026 block groups treated by
TIF and 14,013 block groups
not treated by TIF
1990–2008
Log of employment by industry
and number and value of
building permits
TIF designation had no impact on employment, establishment counts,
or building permits.
Propensity score weighting to deal with potential endogeneity Neutral
Overton, Michael, and Robert L. Bland
(2014)
Dallas, TX 17 TIF districts 1992–2011
Annual amount of private
investment in a TIF district
A $1 increase in public expenditures within a TIF results
in a 20¢ increase in private investment.
Result holds only during recessions Positive
Swenson, Charles W. (2015) California 5,689 census tracts 1980–2000
Changes in measures of
economic well-being, includ-
ing poverty, unemployment,
income, vacancy rate,
employment, and others
TIF districts resulted in minimal positive impacts. TIF adoption treated as endogenous Neutral
Hicks, Michael J., Dagney Faulk, and
Pam Quirin (2015)
Indiana 91 counties 2003–2012
Effective property tax rate,
total assessed values,
and employment
TIF use is associated with increases in assessed value and effective
property tax rates, but also with declines in employment.
TIF adoption not estimated simultaneously Neutral
Hicks, Michael J. , Dagney Faulk, and
Srikant Devaraj (2016)
Indiana 91 counties 2003–2012
Local-option income and sales
taxes and non-TIF
assessed value
TIF use has no impact on retail sales tax or local-option
income tax revenue.
TIF adoption not estimated simultaneously Neutral
Stewart, N. M. (2016) Baltimore, MD 710 block groups 2002–2013
Employment, building permits,
and home sales
TIF had no impact on employment or building permits,
but did stimulate home sales.
Difference-in-difference and propensity score matching used to
assure treated areas and control areas were comparable
Neutral
(slightly positive)
Yadavalli, A., and J. Lander (2017) Indiana
123,000 parcels in 579 TIF
areas
2004–2013
Assessed values, employment,
and wages
TIF increased growth in assessed values by .2%,
but had no impact on employment or wages.
Propensity score weighting to deal with potential endogeneity
Neutral
(slightly positive)
Lester, T. W., and El-Khattabi,
Rachid (2017)
St. Louis and
Kansas City, MO
141 Kansas City census block
groups with TIF and 92
St. Louis block groups with
TIF matched to block groups
without TIF
1990–2012
Employment, sales, and
establishments
TIF had no impact on economic development in either city. Propensity score weighting to deal with potential endogeneity Negative
50 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Table 6, cont’d
Empirical Studies of Effect of TIF on Economic Activity
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 51
Article City, State, or Region Data Time Dependent Variable(s) Finding(s) Notes
Summary
Finding
Carroll, Deborah A. (2008) Milwaukee, WI 12,169 business parcels 1980–1999 Real assessed value Business parcels located in TIF districts grow faster. TIF adoption treated as endogenous Positive
Smith, Brent C. (2009) Chicago, IL
4,022 commercial
property sales
1992 and 2000 Commercial property values
Commercial property values appreciate faster in TIF districts. TIF adoption treated as endogenous Positive
Immergluck, Dan (2009) Atlanta, GA
25,999 house sales near the
BeltLine TIF district
2003–2005 Log of sale price
Announcement of the TIF district caused prices to increase
substantially near some parts of the TIF district.
Effects varied with geography; negative effects in some areas Positive
Byrne, Paul F. (2010) Illinois
1,449 observations in a panel
of municipalities
1980–1999 Employment
On average, TIF has no effect on employment, but industrial TIF
increases employment.
Some controls for endogeneity Neutral
Skidmore, Mark, and Russ Kashian
(2010)
Wisconsin 537 municipalities 1990–2003 Property tax rates
With TIF in place, the property tax rate of nonmunicipal governments
rises, but the property tax rate of municipal governments falls.
Lagged control variables reduce concerns about endogeneity Mixed
Merriman, David F., Mark L. Skidmore,
and Russ D. Kashian (2011)
Wisconsin All municipalities 1990–2003
Real per capita value of
real estate
TIF does not increase in total, residential, or manufacturing property
values, but may increase commercial property values.
Panel data reduce concerns about endogeneity Neutral
Bossard, Jennifer A. (2011) Minnesota
Panel of 334–421 school
districts
1992–2007
Non-TIF district property value
growth for school districts
Increases in TIF intensity result in more rapid growth.
TIF intensity too low to maximize non-TIF school district
property value growth
Positive
Giradi, Anthony G. (2013) Iowa All counties 20022012
Standardized employment
growth and wage growth
TIF had no impact on wage or employment growth.
Actual employment and wages compared to predicted level;
controlling for industrial composition
Neutral
Lester, T. William (2014) Chicago, IL
1,026 block groups treated by
TIF and 14,013 block groups
not treated by TIF
1990–2008
Log of employment by industry
and number and value of
building permits
TIF designation had no impact on employment, establishment counts,
or building permits.
Propensity score weighting to deal with potential endogeneity Neutral
Overton, Michael, and Robert L. Bland
(2014)
Dallas, TX 17 TIF districts 1992–2011
Annual amount of private
investment in a TIF district
A $1 increase in public expenditures within a TIF results
in a 20¢ increase in private investment.
Result holds only during recessions Positive
Swenson, Charles W. (2015) California 5,689 census tracts 1980–2000
Changes in measures of
economic well-being, includ-
ing poverty, unemployment,
income, vacancy rate,
employment, and others
TIF districts resulted in minimal positive impacts. TIF adoption treated as endogenous Neutral
Hicks, Michael J., Dagney Faulk, and
Pam Quirin (2015)
Indiana 91 counties 2003–2012
Effective property tax rate,
total assessed values,
and employment
TIF use is associated with increases in assessed value and effective
property tax rates, but also with declines in employment.
TIF adoption not estimated simultaneously Neutral
Hicks, Michael J. , Dagney Faulk, and
Srikant Devaraj (2016)
Indiana 91 counties 2003–2012
Local-option income and sales
taxes and non-TIF
assessed value
TIF use has no impact on retail sales tax or local-option
income tax revenue.
TIF adoption not estimated simultaneously Neutral
Stewart, N. M. (2016) Baltimore, MD 710 block groups 2002–2013
Employment, building permits,
and home sales
TIF had no impact on employment or building permits,
but did stimulate home sales.
Difference-in-difference and propensity score matching used to
assure treated areas and control areas were comparable
Neutral
(slightly positive)
Yadavalli, A., and J. Lander (2017) Indiana
123,000 parcels in 579 TIF
areas
2004–2013
Assessed values, employment,
and wages
TIF increased growth in assessed values by .2%,
but had no impact on employment or wages.
Propensity score weighting to deal with potential endogeneity
Neutral
(slightly positive)
Lester, T. W., and El-Khattabi,
Rachid (2017)
St. Louis and
Kansas City, MO
141 Kansas City census block
groups with TIF and 92
St. Louis block groups with
TIF matched to block groups
without TIF
1990–2012
Employment, sales, and
establishments
TIF had no impact on economic development in either city. Propensity score weighting to deal with potential endogeneity Negative
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 51
52 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
What is the most appropriate dependent variable? One
might argue that TIF is designed as a tool to stimulate
growth in real estate variables, and therefore it is most
appropriate to focus on property values. However,
the purpose of stimulating growth in property values
is to ultimately improve citizens quality of life, so
employment or median household income would also
be appropriate. Increases in retail sales or building
permits, by contrast, are relatively weak proxies for the
key underlying variables of interest.
Methodology is also important. All but two studies use
some form of regression analyses (Dardia 1998; Kriz
2001). The various data used in the studies are from
city, TIF, and parcel-level observations. Many of the
studies account for potential reverse causality
between TIF use and economic outcomes. This is
important because without reverse causality one
might attribute economic gains to TIF use when, in
fact, the expectation of economic growth was the stim-
ulus for TIF formation in the first place. The differences
in study areas, time periods, outcome variables, and
methodologies make it difficult to generalize about
the findings, however.
Despite this, the last column of table 6 reports a very
concise qualitative summary of each studys finding—
classifying the empirical results as positive (i.e., TIF
promotes economic development), negative (i.e., TIF
reduces growth), and neutral or mixed (both positive
and negative results). In many cases, the concise sum-
mary required a judgment call about which results
were most important and salient. A simple count shows
42 percent of the studies—13 total—have positive
results. Of the remaining 18 studies, 5 have negative re-
sults, 8 have neutral results, and 5 have mixed results.
The neutral results suggest that TIF did little or nothing
to stimulate economic development, so these studies
might be viewed as an argument against the use of
TIF. The mixed results often show very weak positive
effects (Stewart 2016; Yadavalli and Landers 2017) or
strong negative effects (Skidmore and Kashian 2010;
Weber, Bhatta, and Merriman 2003). Also, the most re-
cent studies, which tend to have the strongest data
and best methodologies, are much less positive than
earlier studies. Taken together, this review of the
rigorous evaluation literature suggests that in most
cases, TIF has not accomplished the goal of
promoting economic development.
Taken together, this review of the rigorous
evaluation literature suggests that in most
cases, TIF has not accomplished the goal of
promoting economic development.
Still, there is some evidence that TIF does work in
certain cases. One possible explanation is that TIF
simply works in some locations but not in others. The
empirical research does not support that view, how-
ever: Of the nine studies using Illinois data, three are
positive, two are negative, two are neutral, and two are
mixed. Two of the four studies using Wisconsin data
are positive, but one is neutral and one is mixed.
Two of the five studies from Indiana are positive, but
the three most recent studies show a mostly neutral
effect. Thus, the empirical evidence shows that use of
TIF is no guarantee of success, which suggests using
caution in employing TIF.
Empirical work provides other guidance, too. Several
studies provide evidence that TIF has its strongest
positive effects when used for commercial or mixed
uses (Ingraham, Singer, and Thibodeau 2005; Merri-
man, Skidmore, and Kashian 2011; Smith 2009; Wass-
mer and Anderson 2001; Weber, Bhatta, and Merriman
2003; 2007). However, Dye and Merriman (2000; 2003)
suggest that at least some of the growth in commer-
cial TIF districts is offset by reduced growth in other
nearby areas.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 53
Effects of TIF Adoption on
School Finance
One area of considerable controversy about TIF is its
impact on school finance. Cities are responsible for
establishing and overseeing TIF districts. If some of
the real estate appreciation in a TIF district would
have occurred even in the absence of the TIF district,
overlying school districts may face a diminished tax
base during the life of the TIF district. A school dis-
trict’s fiscal difficulties due to loss of its tax base may
also be exacerbated if the TIF district facilitates new
housing and increased demand for school services.
Some of the revenue lost to the school district in
the short run may be eventually recovered if the TIF
district stimulates additional real estate appreciation.
Even the short-run impact of the TIF district may be
mitigated because many school aid formulas that
depend on property tax base per pupil compensate
school districts, at least to some degree, for the loss
of tax base due to TIF. For example, Illinoiss state-aid
formula subtracts TIF increments from available tax
base per pupil to calculate state aid. Also, TIF revenues
may in some cases be used to finance public spending
that can substitute for school district funding, such as
renovations of parks instead of school playgrounds.
Hence, the net effect of TIF on school finance is
unclear and may be illuminated by further empirical
research. In an environment of scarce resources and
ongoing pressure on the property tax despite its im-
portance as a source of local revenue, it is no wonder
that the impact on school funding continues to be a
major issue.
Table 7 (p. 54) provides basic information about three
empirical studies on TIF’s effect on school finance.
Weber (2003) finds that TIF has no observable impact
on school district tax revenue in the Chicago metropol-
itan area but does raise state aid to school districts.
Similarly, Weber, Hendrick, and Thompson (2008) find
little impact on tax revenues in the Chicago area, but
they do find evidence of lower revenues and higher
tax rates in school districts with TIF in other parts of
Illinois. Nguyen-Hoang (2014) studies the impact of
TIF on school spending in Iowa; in contrast to Weber
(2003), he finds that greater use of TIF is associated
with reduced education expenditures. He finds that
this effect is greater for lower-wealth districts. Taken
together, these findings suggest additional reasons to
be cautious about using TIF.
Other Effects of TIF Adoption
Table 8 (p. 55) gives some basic information about em-
pirical studies that examine other potential effects of
TIF and that cover various related ad hoc topics. Skid-
more, Merriman, and Kashian (2009) provide evidence
that, at least in Wisconsin, TIF encourages municipal
annexation, as TIF districts can be used to improve
municipalities fiscal conditions. Merriman (2010)
provides a simulation analysis that illustrates how the
cycle of TIF adoption and dissolution can make munic-
ipal budgets significantly more difficult to manage, as
TIF gradually supplements available municipal funds
and then those funds suddenly disappear when TIF
is dissolved. In the context of random fluctuations in
assessed value, this can make financial management
significantly more difficult.
Kashian and Skidmore (2011) study factors that
determine the time until a TIF district is dissolved.
They find that TIF districts have longer life spans when
the municipalities that house them—and thus can
decide when they are dissolved—pay smaller shares
of the cost, as measured by the municipal tax rate as
a share of the total. TIF districts were also kept alive
longer following the slow-growth period of the 1991
recession. This finding seems consistent with Dye,
Merriman, and Goulde (2014), who find that TIF dis-
tricts in both Illinois and Nebraska grew significantly
slower during and immediately after the 2008–2009
recession. They find some evidence of a recovery in
TIF growth in Nebraska but little in Illinois.
54 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Hall and Bartels (2014) ask why some Dallas–Ft. Worth
TIF districts are more successful than others and find
that TIF districts using certain formal management
methods, especially performance measurement, have
better outcomes than those that do not. For example,
TIF districts that listed, quantified, and tracked public
versus private initiatives, cost responsibilities, and
success indicators had higher property value growth
than those that did not. On the other hand, risk-
management techniques, such as very detailed and
explicit economic projections, did not significantly
improve the performance of TIF districts.
Kane and Weber (2015) study the relationship between
the type of expenditures in Chicago TIF districts and
the growth rate of property values in those districts.
Disturbingly, they find a clear positive effect resulting
from commercial subsidies but a negative impact from
infrastructure spending. This could suggest that TIF is
ineffective in areas that lack the preconditions (namely,
infrastructure) to support growth. As other studies have
suggested that commercial development in TIF districts
often displaces commercial development elsewhere,
the scope for successful use of TIF may be narrow.
Bland and Overton (2016) study the growth of TIF
districts in Dallas, Texas, and ask whether public or
private investments do more to stimulate real estate
appreciation. They find that public investments, by
themselves, do little to stimulate appreciation, but that
public investment can be a catalyst to stimulate private
investment and promote appreciation when combined
with operational and institutional knowledge.
Table 7
Empirical Studies of Effect of TIF on School Finance
Article
Region or
State
Data
Time
Period
Dependent
Variable(s)
Finding Notes
Summary
Finding
Weber, Rachel
(2003)
Cook County,
Illinois
151 school
districts
1989–
1999
Change in tax
revenue, state
aid, and effective
tax rate
TIF intensity had no
effect on the tax rev-
enue of the school
district, but did raise
state aid.
TIF intensity treat-
ed as endogenous
No impact
Weber, Rachel,
Rebecca
Hendrick,
and Jeremy
Thompson (2008)
Illinois
777 school
districts
2001
Property tax rate
percentage (2001)
and change
in property
tax revenue
(1990–2000)
TIF intensity was
not a determinant of
change in property
tax revenues in the
Chicago metropol-
itan area, but reve-
nues were lowered
in other areas of
Illinois.
Endogeneity not
an issue (munici-
palities choose TIF)
No impact
Nguyen-Hoang,
Phuong (2014)
Iowa
347 school
districts
2001
2011
Log of education
expenditure
TIF is associated
with reduced
education expendi-
tures, especially in
low wealth districts.
Argues that
endogeneity is
not an issue
TIF lowers
education
spending
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 55
Table 8
Empirical Studies About Other TIF-Related Issues
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 55
Article
City or
State
Data
Time
Period
Dependent
Variable(s)
Finding(s) Notes
Skidmore, Mark,
David F. Merriman,
and Russ Kashian
(2009)
Wisconsin
533
municipalities
1990–2003
Log of municipal
land area
Adding a new TIF
district is associated
with annexation.
TIF adoption
treated as
endogenous
Merriman, David F.
(2010)
Simulation,
parameters
mimic Wis-
consin
Simulation,
based on typical
Wisconsin
municipality
Simulation,
based on
2003
parameters
Volatility of
municipal property
tax revenues
The formation and
expiration of TIF districts
can significantly increase
revenue volatility.
Simulation of
municipal
governments'
revenue; overly-
ing governments
not studied
Kashian, Russ, and
Mark Skidmore
(2011)
Wisconsin 362 TIF districts 1988–2009
Lifespans of
TIF districts
Longer TIF lifespans are
associated with smaller
municipal share of the
tax rate and several other
variables.
Parameters
estimated
using duration
analysis
Hall, Jeremy L.,
and Christopher E.
Bartels (2014)
Dallas–Ft.
Worth, TX
72 TIF projects 2007–2008
Difference between
projected assessed
value in the TIF
district and actual
assessed value in
the TIF district
Actual results match
performance results more
closely in TIF districts that
use preimplementation
risk and performance
management.
TIF adoption
not estimated
simultaneously
Dye, Richard F.,
David F. Merriman,
and Katherine
Goulde (2014)
Nebraska
and Illinois
920 Illinois TIF
districts and 297
Nebraska TIF
districts
2006–2013
Growth rate of EAV*
in TIF districts
There was a large decline
in TIF EAV after the start
of the Great Recession in
Illinois, but the recession
had less of an effect in
Nebraska.
Young TIF
districts grow
faster than more
mature districts
in both states
Kane, Kevin, and
Rachel Weber (2015)
Chicago, IL 160 TIF districts 2002–2012
Growth rate of EAV*
in TIF districts
Commercial TIF subsidies
result in faster property-
value growth than other
types of expenditures.
Research sug-
gests important
symbolic effect
of TIF district
Bland, R. L., and M.
Overton (2016)
Dallas, TX
18 TIF districts,
212 observa-
tions
Not
provided
Growth rate of EAV*
in TIF districts
Private investments
stimulate more growth
than public investments,
but there is interaction
between these two types
of investments.
No correction
for possibility
that private
investments
are attracted to
rapidly growing
areas
Note: *EAV: equalized assessed value.
56 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
CHAPTER 8
Conclusion
Although TIF has been used across many states for
years, there is still much we do not know about how its
use affects economic development. Nonetheless, the
information summarized in this report provides a strong
factual basis for certain findings and recommendations
as we continue to monitor and research this tool.
TIF was used to help fund the Millennium
Park in Chicago. Photo: Serge Melki/Flickr
CC BY 2.0.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 57
Findings
1. Tax increment financing is an important and
widely used tool to promote economic develop-
ment, especially in areas facing blight and other
significant economic challenges. TIF performs
best when the public and private sectors work
together to stimulate economic development. TIF
can be a useful tool to create commitments that
engender trust among the various parties involved
and lead to successful implementation of devel-
opment plans.
2. Unfortunately, the design of TIF in many states
makes it vulnerable to exploitation by cities,
which can obtain revenues that otherwise would
have gone to overlying governments, especially
school districts.
3. TIF has been used very unevenly across states,
with extensive use in Midwestern states, for ex-
ample, but little use in other regions of the coun-
try. The reasons for the uneven use of TIF have not
been rigorously studied, but it is reasonable to
speculate that states responses to their neigh-
bors use of TIF has contributed to this pattern of
unevenness.
4. Within individual states and cities, most often TIF
has been used in areas that were already moder-
ately successful, and it has done little to stimu-
late growth in the most depressed areas.
5. Transparency in the use of TIF is a huge challenge,
and state monitoring of TIF use is very uneven. City
reporting about TIF is also mixed. Even in cities
like Chicago, where TIF is used extensively and
where much information has been made public,
the transparency of TIF remains inconsistent.
6. Many academic studies of TIF suggest that it often
fails to deliver economic growth beyond what oth-
erwise would have occurred and may often simply
result in the relocation of economic activity.
7. Academic studies suggest a variety of unintended
effects that may result from TIF use. These include
diminished or reallocated school revenues and
increased budget volatility, especially during
unstable economic cycles.
8. Recent research suggests that more attention to
the management of TIF and the type of spending
within TIF districts could lead to a better under-
standing of why some TIF districts succeed and
others do not.
58 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Recommendations
1. States should track and monitor TIF use.
Basic monitoring helps states evaluate the use of
TIF and helps state legislators better understand
whether TIF regulations are achieving their goals.
Virtually all states are involved in monitoring the
property tax assessment processes of local gov-
ernments and could easily report on the number
of TIF districts and the base and incremental val-
ue in each district in each year. Some states, such
as Wisconsin and Illinois, require regular reporting
on TIF and can serve as models for other states.
Wisconsin provides a particularly strong example,
as it requires detailed delineation of expenditures
and information about the movement of TIF funds
from one TIF district to another, known as porting.
Wisconsin could improve its reports (Wisconsin
Department of Revenue 2017b) by requiring infor-
mation about TIF-related borrowing.
2. States should revise statutes to allow counties,
school districts, and other overlying local govern-
ments to opt out of contributing resources to TIF
districts. This measure would diminish or elimi-
nate the incentive for cities to use TIF as a device
to capture revenues that otherwise would have
gone to overlying governments. TIF districts can
be particularly problematic for overlying govern-
ments when combined with tax limitations, which
can prevent the districts from recouping revenue
lost to TIF districts. Recent legislation allowing
transit TIFs in Chicago may provide a model for
this kind of policy.
3. State legislators should review their states “but
for” TIF requirements to determine whether they
are effective. An effective “but for” requirement
can reduce reliance on TIF when other tools might
be more helpful and transparent. If a states
requirement is not effective, that state should
consider revisions that place realistic limits on
local governments use of TIF. Californias recent
revisions of rules on TIF might provide useful guid-
ance in this area.
4. Local governments should provide extensive, eas-
ily accessible information about TIF use, revenues,
and expenditures. This information would enable
local elected officials to monitor and regulate the
application of this tool. Local legislative bodies
(e.g., city councils) should require regular reports
from executive officers that document progress
toward clearly articulated goals for the use of TIF.
Local legislators should consider policies that
require periodic reports on the administration of
TIF districts, and they should have the option of
directing staff to dissolve TIF districts that do
not meet the jurisdictions objectives. They could
also use the evidence-based approach to make
adjustments, such as limiting the duration of
TIF mechanisms.
5. Researchers should study, document, and ex-
plain the different outcomes of TIF use in various
geographic areas. To date, academic studies of TIF
document mixed outcomes but do not clearly iden-
tify factors that explain this variation. Such studies
should also expand knowledge about the types
of TIF expenditures that best promote economic
development.
Evidence suggests that implementing these recommen-
dations will improve tax increment financing and make
it a useful tool for economic development that contrib-
utes to strong, fiscally sustainable communities.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 59
NY
30Tax Increment Development
LA
YY
30Tax Increment Financing Districts
KY
NY
20Tax Increment Financing Districts
KS
YY
25Tax Increment Financing Districts
IN
NY
23
Tax Increment Allocation Redevelopment
Areas
IL
NY
24Revenue Allocation Areas
ID
YY
20Urban Renewal Areas
IA
NN
Term of
bonds
Tax Increment Financing Districts
HI
NY
Term of
bonds
Tax Allocation Districts
GA
NY
7–40Community Development
FL
NY
30Municipal Tax Increment Financing Districts
DE
NN
Varies by
district
Tax Increment Financing
DC
YY
40Tax Increment Financing Districts
CT
NY
25–50Tax Increment Financing Districts
CO
NY
45Enhanced Infrastructure Financing Districts
CA
N/AN/A
AZ
YY
25Redevelopment Districts
AR
YY
30Tax Increment Districts
AL
NN
40Improvement Area Projects
AK
DAO
2
TCRASTSBCOCTO
1
DPPBPPCPCBFSBFB
Duration
(years)
Program NameState
Public
Hearing
Required?
Approval
Agencies
Requirements for District Creation
Appendix
State Tax Increment Finance Programs
60 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
A: Authorization
D: Deal
Approval
CT: City
CO: County
SB: School Board or District
ST: State
RA: Community Redevelopment
Agency Board
TC: TIF Commission
O: Other
B: Blight
BF: “But For” Test
FS: Feasibility Study
CB: Cost-Benefit Analysis
CP: Consistent with Comprehensive Plan or
Development Plan
PP: Project Plan
PB: Finding of Public Benefit
DP: Finding of Development Potential
O: Other
2142126141110354912334413171834Totals
YY
25Tax Increment Financing
WY
YY
30Tax Increment Financing
WV
YY
20–27Tax Incremental Districts
WI
NY
30Tax Increment Financing
WA
YY
20Tax Increment Financing Districts
VT
NY
Term of
bonds
Tax Increment Financing Districts
VA
NN
UnknownTax Increment Financing Districts
UT
NY
20Tax Increment Reinvestment Zones
TX
YY
UnknownTax Increment Financing
TN
NY
20Tax Incremental Districts
SD
NY
30
Tax Increment Financing
for Redevelopment Projects
SC
NN
UnspecifiedTax Increment Financing Areas
RI
YY
20Tax Incremental Financing Districts
PA
NY
UnspecifiedUrban Renewal Plans
OR
YY
25Tax Increment Financing Districts
OK
NN
30Tax Increment Financing Districts
OH
YY
UnspecifiedTax Increment Financing
NY
NY
20TIF and Redevelopment Areas
NV
NY
10–20Tax Increment Development Districts
NM
NN
UnspecifiedRevenue Allocation District Financing
NJ
NY
Term of
bonds
Tax Increment Financing in
Development Districts
NH
YY
15
Tax Increment Financing for
Redevelopment Projects
NE
YY
30Tax Increment Financing
ND
NY
30Project Development Financing (TIF)
NC
NY
15–40Tax Increment Financing
MT
YY
30Tax Increment Financing
MS
YY
23Real Property Tax Increment Allocation
MO
YY
25Tax Increment Financing
MN
YY
Term of
bonds
Tax Increment Financing
MI
YY
30Tax Increment Financing Districts
ME
NN
UnspecifiedTax Increment Financing Districts
MD
NY
20District Improvement Financing
MA
DAO
2
TCRASTSBCOCTO
1
DPPBPPCPCBFSBFB
Duration
(years)
Program NameState
Public
Hearing
Required?
Approval
Agencies
Requirements for District Creation
Appendix, cont’d
State Tax Increment Finance Programs
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 61
A: Authorization
D: Deal
Approval
CT: City
CO: County
SB: School Board or District
ST: State
RA: Community Redevelopment
Agency Board
TC: TIF Commission
O: Other
B: Blight
BF: “But For” Test
FS: Feasibility Study
CB: Cost-Benefit Analysis
CP: Consistent with Comprehensive Plan or
Development Plan
PP: Project Plan
PB: Finding of Public Benefit
DP: Finding of Development Potential
O: Other
2142126141110354912334413171834Totals
YY
25Tax Increment Financing
WY
YY
30Tax Increment Financing
WV
YY
20–27Tax Incremental Districts
WI
NY
30Tax Increment Financing
WA
YY
20Tax Increment Financing Districts
VT
NY
Term of
bonds
Tax Increment Financing Districts
VA
NN
UnknownTax Increment Financing Districts
UT
NY
20Tax Increment Reinvestment Zones
TX
YY
UnknownTax Increment Financing
TN
NY
20Tax Incremental Districts
SD
NY
30
Tax Increment Financing
for Redevelopment Projects
SC
NN
UnspecifiedTax Increment Financing Areas
RI
YY
20Tax Incremental Financing Districts
PA
NY
UnspecifiedUrban Renewal Plans
OR
YY
25Tax Increment Financing Districts
OK
NN
30Tax Increment Financing Districts
OH
YY
UnspecifiedTax Increment Financing
NY
NY
20TIF and Redevelopment Areas
NV
NY
10–20Tax Increment Development Districts
NM
NN
UnspecifiedRevenue Allocation District Financing
NJ
NY
Term of
bonds
Tax Increment Financing in
Development Districts
NH
YY
15
Tax Increment Financing for
Redevelopment Projects
NE
YY
30Tax Increment Financing
ND
NY
30Project Development Financing (TIF)
NC
NY
15–40Tax Increment Financing
MT
YY
30Tax Increment Financing
MS
YY
23Real Property Tax Increment Allocation
MO
YY
25Tax Increment Financing
MN
YY
Term of
bonds
Tax Increment Financing
MI
YY
30Tax Increment Financing Districts
ME
NN
UnspecifiedTax Increment Financing Districts
MD
NY
20District Improvement Financing
MA
DAO
2
TCRASTSBCOCTO
1
DPPBPPCPCBFSBFB
Duration
(years)
Program NameState
Public
Hearing
Required?
Approval
Agencies
Requirements for District Creation
Sources: Updated from Kenyon, Langley, and Paquin (2012) using Significant Features of the Property Tax and various state sources and statutes.
1
Other Requirements for District Creation: CA, impact report; CT, creation of local development agency; DC, potential for tax revenue growth; FL, shortage of affordable housing;
GA, deterioration and inadequate infrastructure; IL, housing impact study and map of land uses to be funded; IA, slum or economic development need; ME, suitability
for commercial uses; MD, resolution designating area and pledge of revenue; MT, inadequate infrastructure; NM, no net expense; VA, development needs.
2
Other Approval Agencies: DE, delegated by bond issuer; IA, community colleges; IL, Joint Review Board; KS, county and state in some cases; MN, governing board of authority;
MT, urban renewal authority; OH, Tax Incentive Review Council; OK, review committee; SC, affected taxing entities; WA, fire protection district; WI, Joint Review Board;
WY, planning commission.
62 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
References
Anderson, John E. 1990. “Tax Increment Financing: Municipal
Adoption and Growth. National Tax Journal 43(2): 155–163.
Atlanta BeltLine. 2013. “2030 Strategic Implementation Plan Final
Report. http://beltlineorg.wpengine.netdna-cdn.com/wp-content
/uploads/2013/03/Beltline_Implementation-Plan_web.pdf.
Barker, Jacob, and Tim Bryant. 2016. “New $170 Million Cortex
Development to Add Hotel, Apartments, Parking Garage. St. Louis
Post-Dispatch, October 16.
Bartik, T. J. 2017. A New Panel Database on Business Incentives for
Economic Development Offered by State and Local Governments
in the United States. Kalamazoo, MI: W. E. Upjohn Institute for
Employment Research.
Bland, R. L., and M. Overton. 2016. Assessing the Contributions
of Collaborators in Public-Private Partnerships: Evidence
from Tax Increment Financing.The American Review of Public
Administration 46(4): 418–435.
Blocher, J., and J. Q. Morgan. 2008. “Questions About Tax
Increment Financing in North Carolina.Community and Economic
Development Bulletin 5: 1964. https://scholarship.law.duke.edu
/cgi/viewcontent.cgi?article=2597&context=faculty_scholarship.
Bossard, Jennifer A. 2011. “The Effect of Tax Increment Financing
on Spillovers and School District Revenue. Ph.D. Dissertation
(economics). Lincoln, NE: University of Nebraska.
Bossard, Jennifer A., and Mike Korsakas. 2017. “Tax Increment
Finance in Nebraska: A Review of TIF Use from 1996–2011.
Economics & Business Journal: Inquiries & Perspectives 8(1):
94–115.
Brown, Ron. 2015. State Assessor for Alaska. Phone call with
David Merriman about the use of tax increment finance in Alaska.
May 12.
Brueckner, Jan K. 2001. “Tax Increment Financing: A Theoretical
Inquiry.Journal of Public Economics 81: 321–343.
Byrne, Paul F. 2005. “Strategic Interaction and the Adoption of
Tax Increment Financing.Regional Science and Urban Economics
35(3): 279–303.
—. 2006. “Determinants of Property Value Growth for Tax
Increment Financing Districts. Economic Development Quarterly
20(4): 317–329.
—. 2010. “Does Tax Increment Financing Deliver on Its Promise
of Jobs? The Impact of Tax Increment Financing on Municipal
Employment Growth. Economic Development Quarterly 24(1):
13–22.
California Legislative Information. 2015.AB-2 Community
Revitalization Authority. https://leginfo.legislature.ca.gov/faces
/billAnalysisClient.xhtml?bill_id=201520160AB2.
Carroll, Deborah A. 2008. “Tax Increment Financing and Property
Value: An Examination of Business Property Using Panel Data.
Urban Affairs Review 43(4): 520–552.
Carroll, Deborah A., and Robert J. Eger. 2006. “Brownfields, Crime,
and Tax Increment Financing. The American Review of Public
Administration 36(4): 455–477.
City of Chicago.Annual Financial Analysis 2016. http://chicago
.github.io/annual-financial-analysis/.
City of Chicago, TIF Reform Panel. 2011. “Findings and
Recommendations for Reforming the Use of Tax Increment
Financing in Chicago: Creating Greater Efficiency, Transparency
and Accountability.
City of Chicago, Department of Planning and Development. 2018.
“Tax Increment Financing.” www.cityofchicago.org/city/en/depts
/dcd/provdrs/tif.html.
City of Dallas, Office of Economic Development. 2011/2014. “The
Deep Ellum TIF District Project Plan and Reinvestment Zone
Financing Plan. http://www.dallasecodev.org/DocumentCenter
/View/354/Deep-Ellum-TIF-District-Plan-Amended-2014-PDF.
—. 2014. “Deep Ellum TIF District. www.dallasecodev.org/367
/Deep-Ellum-TIF-District.
Coleman, Denny, and Brian Murphy. 2014. “Economic
Development. Better Together St. Louis. www.bettertogetherstl
.com/wp-content/uploads/2014/05/Better-Together-Economic-
Development-Report-FULL-REPORT.pdf.
Council of Development Finance Agencies. 2008. “TIF State-
by-State Report. www.bettertogetherstl.com/wp-content
/uploads/2014/05/State-TIF-Survey-State-by-State.pdf.
—. 2017. “CDFA Tax Increment Finance Resource Center.” cdfa.
net/cdfa/cdfaweb.nsf/0/ACA4D2FF55BE29E18825793600699D8F.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 63
Dardia, Michael. 1998. Subsidizing Redevelopment in California.
San Francisco, CA: Public Policy Institute of California.
Dye, Richard F., and David F. Merriman. 2000. “The Effects of Tax
Increment Financing on Economic Development.Journal of Urban
Economics 47(2): 306–328.
—. 2003. “The Effect of Tax Increment Financing on Land Use.
In The Property Tax, Land Use, and Land Use Regulation, Ed. Dick
Netzer. Northampton, MA: Edward Elgar Publishing.
Dye, Richard F., David F. Merriman, and Katherine Goulde. 2014.
“Tax Increment Financing and the Great Recession.National Tax
Journal 67(3): 697.
East-West Gateway Council of Governments. 2011. An Assessment
of the Effectiveness and Fiscal Impacts of the Use of Development
Incentives in the St. Louis Region.” https://www.ewgateway.org
/wp-content/uploads/2017/08/TIFFinalRpt.pdf.
Felix, R. Alison, and James R. Hines. 2013. “Who Offers Tax-Based
Business Development Incentives?” Journal of Urban Economics
75: 80–91.
Florida, Richard. 2017. “Handing Out Tax Breaks to Businesses
Is Worse Than Useless. CityLab. https://www.citylab.com
/life/2017/03/business-tax-incentives-waste/518754/.
General Assembly of the State of Indiana. 2014. “Senate Enrolled
Act No. 118. http://iga.in.gov/static-documents/b/a/3/5
/ba35cbe5/SB0118.05.ENRS.pdf.
Gibson, Diane. 2003. “Neighborhood Characteristics and the
Targeting of Tax Increment Financing in Chicago. Journal of Urban
Economics 54(2): 309–327.
Giradi, Anthony G. 2013. “Iowa Tax Increment Financing Tax Credits
Program Evaluation Study.” Iowa Department of Revenue, Tax
Research, and Program Analysis Section. (December). https://tax
.iowa.gov/sites/files/idr/TIF%20Evaluation%20Study%202013.pdf.
Greenbaum, Robert T., and Jim Landers. 2014. “The Tiff Over TIF:
A Review of the Literature Examining the Effectiveness of the Tax
Increment Financing.National Tax Journal 67(3): 655.
Hall, Jeremy L., and Christopher E. Bartels. 2014. “Management
Practice Variation in Tax Increment Financing Districts:
An Empirical Examination of the Administrative Theory of
Performance. Economic Development Quarterly 28(3): 270–282.
Harrington, Tom. 2017. JDLC and MSU Extension Agent for Jefferson
County. Personal interview by David Merriman. March 21.
Herr, Robert C., Noa L. Clark, and Paul C. Levin. 2012. “Californias
Post Redevelopment Agency Landscape. Perspectives on Real
Estate Newsletter. Pillsbury Winthrop Shaw Pittman LLP.
Hicks, Michael J., Dagney Faulk, and Pam Quirin. 2015. “Some
Economic Effects of Tax Increment Financing in Indiana. Ball State
University Center for Business and Economic Research. http://
media.mwcradio.com/mimesis/2015-02/04/tif%20study%20
from%20ball%20state.pdf.
Hicks, Michael J., Dagney Faulk, and Srikant Devaraj. 2016. “Tax
Increment Financing.” Ball State University Center for Business
and Economic Research. http://projects.cberdata.org/reports
/FiscalTIF-20160129.pdf.
Houde, Gary. 2017. Senior Research Analyst Idaho State Tax
Commission, Property Tax Division. Email communication.
September 26.
ICMA (International City/County Management Association). 2014.
“ICMA Survey Research: Economic Development Survey Results
2014. http://icma.org/en/icma/knowledge_network/documents
/kn/Document/306723/ICMA_Economic_Development_Survey_
Results_2014.
Illinois Department of Revenue. 2015. Property Tax Statistics,
Table 14A. www.revenue.state.il.us/AboutIdor/TaxStats
/PropertyTaxStats/2015/.
Illinois Tax Increment Allocation Redevelopment Act. Amended
2014. 65 ILCS 5/11-74.4-1 –11-74.411 http://ilga.gov/legislation
/ilcs/ilcs4.asp?DocName=006500050HArt%2E+11+Div%2E+
74%2E4&ActID=802&ChapterID=14&SeqStart=208900000&
SeqEnd=211000000.
Immergluck, Dan. 2009. “Large Redevelopment Initiatives, Housing
Values, and Gentrification: The Case of the Atlanta BeltLine.Urban
Studies 46(8): 1723–1745.
Ingraham, Allan T., Hal J. Singer, and Thomas G. Thibodeau. 2005.
“Inter-City Competition for Retail Trade: Can Tax Increment
Financing Generate Incremental Tax Receipts?” SSRN 766925.
Johnson, Craig. 2002. “Tax Increment Financing. National
Association of Realtors. http://archive.realtor.org/sites/default
/files/Tax%20Increment%20Financing.pdf.
64 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Johnson, Craig L., and Kenneth Kritz. 2001. A Review of State
Tax Increment Financing Laws.” In Tax Increment Financing and
Economic Development: Uses, Structures, and Impact, Ed. Craig L.
Johnson and Joyce Y. Man. Albany, NY: SUNY Press.
Kane, Kevin, and Rachel Weber. 2015. “Municipal Investment and
Property Value Appreciation in Chicagos Tax Increment Financing
Districts. Journal of Planning Education and Research 3(2):
167181.
Kashian, Russ, and Mark Skidmore. 2011. A Duration Analysis of
Tax Increment Finance District Lifespan: The Case of Wisconsin.
Working paper. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
www.lincolninst.edu/pubs/1960_A-Duration-Analysis-of-Tax
-Increment-Finance-District-Lifespans-The-Case-of-Wisconsin.
Kenyon, D. A., A. H. Langley, and B. P. Paquin. 2012. Rethinking
Property Tax Incentives for Business. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln
Institute of Land Policy.
Kirth, Rob, and Phineas Baxandall. 2011. “Tax-Increment
Financing: The Need for Increased Transparency and
Accountability in Local Economic Development Subsidies.” Denver,
CO: U.S. PIRG Education Fund.
Knezevic, Chris. 2017 “Municipalities Experiencing Growing Pains
with GASB 77. Development Incentives Quarterly. https://www
.vorys.com/newsletter-778.html.
Kriz, Kenneth A. 2001. “The Effect of Tax Increment Finance on
Local Government Financial Condition.Municipal Finance Journal
22(1): 41–64.
LaPlante, Josephine M. 2001. “Who Uses Tax Increment Financing?
Local Government Adoption Catalysts. Municipal Finance Journal
22(1): 79–97.
Langley, A. H., D. A. Kenyon, and P. C. Bailin. 2012. “Payments in
Lieu of Taxes by Nonprofits: Which Nonprofits Make PILOTS and
Which Localities Receive Them?” Working paper. Cambridge, MA:
Lincoln Institute of Land Policy.
League of California Cities. 2016. “Community Revitalization and
Investment Authorities.” https://www.cacities.org/Resources
-Documents/Policy-Advocacy-Section/Hot-Issues/New-Tax
-Increment-Tools/AB-2-Summary-10-6-15.aspx.
Lefcoe, George, and Charles W. Swenson. 2014. “Redevelopment in
California: The Demise of TIF-Funded Redevelopment in California
and Its Aftermath.National Tax Journal 67: 14–18.
Lemov, Penelope. 2010. “Tough Times for TIFs?” Governing.
www.governing.com/topics/finance/tough-times-tax-increment
-financing.html.
LeRoy, Greg. 2017. “Early Tax Abatement Disclosures Under GASB
77: Incomplete, Mislabeled—and Occasionally Spectacular
(Corrected).” Daily Tax Report: Bloomberg BNA. June 14. www
.goodjobsfirst.org/sites/default/files/docs/pdfs/06_14_17_Greg
_LeRoy_Insight_Corrected.pdf.
Lester, T. William. 2014. “Does Chicagos Tax Increment Financing
(TIF) Programme Pass the ‘But-for’ Test? Job Creation and
Economic Development Impacts Using Time-Series Data. Urban
Studies 51(4): 655–674.
Lester, T. William, and Rachid El-Khattabi. 2017. “Does Tax-
Increment Financing Pass the ‘But ForTest in Missouri?” Kansas
City, MO: Show-Me Institute. https://showmeinstitute.org.
Lincoln Institute of Land Policy and the George Washington
Institute of Public Policy. 2018. “Significant Features of the
Property Tax. http://datatoolkits.lincolninst.edu/subcenters
/significant-features-property-tax/Report_Incentives_for
_Economic Development.aspx.
Luby, Martin J., and Tima Moldogaziev. 2014. “Tax Increment Debt
Finance and the Great Recession.National Tax Journal 67(3): 675.
Maine Legislature Revised Statutes. 2017. “Title 30-A:
Municipalities and Counties.” http:/legislature.maine.gov
/statutes/30-A/title30-Ach0sec0.html.
Man, Joyce Y. 1999a. “Fiscal Pressure, Tax Competition, and
the Adoption of Tax Increment Financing.Urban Studies 36(7):
11511167.
—. 1999b. “The Impact of Tax Increment Financing Programs
on Local Economic Development.Journal of Public Budgeting
Accounting and Financial Management 11(3): 417–430.
Man, Joyce Y., and Mark S. Rosentraub. 1998. “Tax Increment
Financing: Municipal Adoption and Effects on Property Value
Growth.Public Finance Review 26(6): 523–547.
Mason, Susan, and Kenneth P. Thomas. 2010. “Tax Increment
Financing in Missouri: An Analysis of Determinants, Competitive
Dynamics, Equity, and Path Dependency.Economic Development
Quarterly 24(2): 169–179.
Merriman, David F. 2010. “Does TIF Make It More Difficult to
Manage Municipal Budgets? A Simulation Model and Directions
for Future Research.” In Municipal Revenues and Land Policies,
Ed. Gregory Ingram and Yu-Hung Hong. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln
Institute of Land Policy.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 65
Merriman, David F., Di Qiao, and Tianshu Zhao. 2018. “Evidence
About State-by-State Use of Tax Increment Financing. https://
ssrn.com/abstract=3144474. March 20.
Merriman, David F., Mark L. Skidmore, and Russ D. Kashian. 2011.
“Do Tax Increment Finance Districts Stimulate Growth in Real
Estate Values?” Real Estate Economics 39(2): 221250.
Minnesota House of Representatives, House Research Department.
2017. “TIF District Types: Applicable Limits and Characteristics.
www.house.leg.state.mn.us/hrd/issinfo/tif/dist
.aspx.
Minnesota Office of the Legislative Auditor, Program Evaluation
Division. 1996. “Tax Increment Financing.” March. https://www
.auditor.leg.state.mn.us/ped/1996/pe9606.htm.
Missouri Office of State Auditor. 2018. Tax Increment Financing
Reports. https://app.auditor.mo.gov/TIF/SearchTIF.aspx.
Moody’s Investor Service. 2012. “U.S. Municipal Bond Defaults
and Recoveries, 1970–2011. Special Comment. www.nhhefa.com
/documents/moodysMunicipalDefaultStudy1970-2011.pdf.
Nguyen-Hoang, Phuong. 2014. “Tax Increment Financing and
Education Expenditures: The Case of Iowa.Education Finance and
Policy 9(4): 515–540.
Office of the Cook County Clerk. 2016. “TIF District Summary:
City of Chicago Only 2014 to 2015 Revenue Comparison.” https://
www.cookcountyclerk.com/sites/default/files/pdfs
/ChicagoTIFTotalsSummary2015.pdf.
Otto, Rebecca. 2017. Tax Increment Financing Legislative Report.
Office of the State Auditor, State of Minnesota. www.osa.state
.mn.us/reports/tif/2015/tifLegislative/tifLegislative_15_report.pdf.
Overton, Michael, and Robert L. Bland. 2014. “The Great Recessions
Impact on Credible Commitment: An Analysis of Private Investment
in Tax Increment Financing Districts.State and Local Government
Review 46(4): 282–297.
Petersen, Jennifer A. 2007. “The State of Tax Increment Financing in
the United States. State Tax Notes (August 27): 601–604.
Quigley, Mike. 2007. A Tale of Two Cities: Reinventing Tax Increment
Financing.” https://www.heartland.org/policy-documents/tale
-two-cities-reinventing-tax-increment-financing.
Reingold, D. A. 2001. Are TIFs Being Misused to Alter Patterns of
Residential Segregation? The Case of Addison and Chicago, Illinois.
In Tax Increment Financing and Economic Development: Uses,
Structures, and Impact, Ed. Craig L. Johnson and Joyce Y. Man.
Albany, NY: SUNY Press.
Rogers, Cynthia L., and Jill L. Tao. 2004. “Quasi-Experimental
Analysis of Targeted Economic Development Programs: Lessons
from Florida.Economic Development Quarterly 18(3): 269–285.
St. Louis Development Corporation. 2018. A Summary of TIF
Redevelopment Projects for the City of St. Louis. https://www
.stlouis-mo.gov/government/departments/sldc/documents
/upload/TIF-PROJECTS-MATRIX-SLDC-Web.pdf.
Skidmore, Mark, and Russ Kashian. 2010. “On the Relationship
Between Tax Increment Finance and Property Taxation.Regional
Science and Urban Economics 40(6): 407–414.
Skidmore, Mark, David Merriman, and Russ Kashian. 2009. “The
Relationship Between Tax Increment Finance and Municipal Land
Annexation.Land Economics 85.4: 598–613.
Smith, Brent C. 2006. “The Impact of Tax Increment Finance
Districts on Localized Real Estate: Evidence from Chicagos
Multifamily Markets.Journal of Housing Economics 15(1): 21–37.
—. 2009. “If You Promise to Build It, Will They Come? The
Interaction Between Local Economic Development Policy and
the Real Estate Market: Evidence from Tax Increment Finance
Districts. Real Estate Economics 37(2): 209–234.
Springer, Heidi. 2015. “CDFA / BNY Mellon Development Finance
Webcast Series: Framing the National Incentives Discussion.
Council of Development Finance Agencies. www.cdfa.net/cdfa
/cdfaweb.nsf/ord.html?open&tag=Webcasts.
Stewart, N. M. 2016. “Where the Jobs Are: Evaluating the Impact
of Tax Increment Financing (TIF) on Local Employment and Private
Investment in Baltimore City. Doctoral dissertation. Baltimore,
MD: University of Maryland.
Swenson, Charles W. 2015. “The Death of California
Redevelopment Areas: Did the State Get It Right?” Economic
Development Quarterly 29(3): 211–228.
Torres, Paco. 2016.AB 2492 (Alejo): Cleanup for CRIA
Implementation (AB 2). www.caled.org/wp-content
/uploads/2014/12/AB-2492-CRIA-Cleanup-Fact-Sheet-Final.pdf.
Vance, Steven. 2016. “Transit TIF Districts Pass State House and
Senate, Would Fund CTA Projects.Streets Blog Chicago. June 30.
http://chi.streetsblog.org/2016/06/30/transit-tif-districts-pass
-state-house-and-senate-would-fund-major-cta-projects.
Warner, Mildred E., and Lingwen Zheng. 2013. “Business Incentive
Adoption in the Recession.Economic Development Quarterly
27(2): 90–101.
66 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
Wassmer, Robert W. 1994. “Can Local Incentives Alter a
Metropolitan Citys Economic Development?” Urban Studies 31(8):
12511278.
Wassmer, Robert W., and John E. Anderson. 2001. “Bidding for
Business: New Evidence on the Effect of Locally Offered Economic
Development Incentives in a Metropolitan Area. Economic
Development Quarterly 15(2): 132–148.
Weber, Rachel. 2003. “Equity and Entrepreneurialism: The Impact
of Tax Increment Financing on School Finance.Urban Affairs
Review 38(5): 619–644.
—. 2010. “Selling City Futures: The Financialization of Urban
Redevelopment Policy.Economic Geography 86(3): 251–274.
Weber, Rachel, Rebecca Hendrick, and Jeremy Thompson.
2008. “The Effect of Tax Increment Financing on School District
Revenues: Regional Variation and Interjurisdictional Competition.
State and Local Government Review 40(1:) 27–41.
Weber, Rachel, Saurav Dev Bhatta, and David Merriman. 2003.
“Does Tax Increment Financing Raise Urban Industrial Property
Values? Urban Studies 40(10): 20012021.
—. 2007. “Spillovers from Tax Increment Financing Districts:
Implications for Housing Price Appreciation. Regional Science and
Urban Economics 37(2): 259–281.
Webster, Keeley. 2015. “Redevelopment Inches Back in California.
The Bond Buyer. https://www.bondbuyer.com/news
/redevelopment-inches-back-in-california.
Wisconsin Department of Revenue. 2017a. “City/Village Tax
Incremental Financing (TIF) Manual. https://www.revenue.wi.gov
/Pages/Publications/slf-tif-cvmanual.aspx.
Wisconsin Department of Revenue. 2017b. Tax Incremental
Financing (TIF). Information. https://www.revenue.wi.gov/Pages
/SLF/tif.aspx.
Wisconsin State Legislature. 2018. “Tax Increment Law. http://
docs.legis.wisconsin.gov/statutes/statutes/66/XI/1105/4m
/c?view=section.%20In.
Yadavalli, A., and J. Landers. 2017. “Tax Increment Financing: A
Propensity Score Approach.Economic Development Quarterly
31(4): 312–325.
Youngman, Joan. 2016. A Good Tax. Cambridge, MA: Lincoln
Institute of Land Policy.
MERRIMAN | IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT | 67
The author thanks the following Lincoln Institute of Land Policy staff for
their helpful comments on the work in progress and other contributions:
Lourdes Germán, director of International and Institute-Wide Initiatives;
Daphne Kenyon, fellow, Department of Valuation and Taxation; Emily
McKeigue, managing editor; and Joan Youngman, senior fellow and chair of
the Department of Valuation and Taxation.
The author also thanks:
Catherine Collins, research professor and interim associate director of the
George Washington Institute of Public Policy, and her staff for assistance
in using information compiled from the Significant Features of the
Property Tax database;
Tianshu Zhao and Di Qiao, University of Illinois Chicago Ph.D. students, for
their help in gathering data about the number of TIF districts in each state
and Chuanyi Guo, University of Illinois Chicago Ph.D. student, for his work
on various aspects of the project;
Alyssa Conley, former Lincoln Institute of Land Policy research assistant,
for her work on early drafts of several case studies;
Margaret Cusack, research manager, International Association of
Assessing Officers (IAAO), and William Lester, associate professor,
Department of City and Regional Planning, University of North Carolina
Chapel Hill, for reviewing the manuscript and offering helpful comments;
Richard Dye, emeritus professor of economics, Lake Forest College,
and Rachel Weber, professor, Department of Urban Planning and Policy,
University of Illinois Chicago, for their colleagueship and insights; and
Property tax professionals from around the United States too numerous to
mention individually for feedback during many stages of this report.
Although the author integrated comments and ideas from the individuals
listed here, the final report does not necessarily represent the views of
these individuals or their organizations.
Acknowledgments
68 | POLICY FOCUS REPORT | LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
ABOUT THE AUTHOR
David Merriman is the James J. Stukel Presidential Professor in the
Department of Public Administration and the Institute of Government
and Public Affairs at the University of Illinois Chicago. He serves as a
member of the board of the National Tax Association, an associate editor
of Economic Development Quarterly, and a fellow at the Lincoln Institute
of Land Policy. He previously served as a senior research associate at
the Urban Institute and as a visiting scholar at the New England Public
Policy Center, Federal Reserve Bank of Boston. Merriman has expertise
in state and local public finance and urban economic development.
Some of his current research projects focus on state and local gov-
ernment business taxation, public school teacher pension policy, and
illicit tobacco markets. His research has been funded by the John D.
and Catherine T. MacArthur Foundation, the Volcker Alliance, the Robert
Wood Johnson Foundation, the World Bank, and grants from local, state,
and national governments. His research has been published in many
peer review journals and he is frequently quoted in local and national
news media. He earned a doctorate in economics from the University of
Wisconsin–Madison and a bachelor’s degree in economics and political
science from American University.
Front Cover: Founded in 2002, the Cortex Innovation District
in St. Louis is the Midwest’s innovation hub of development,
bioscience and technology research, and commercialization
for start-up programs and established companies in the area.
Top: An intersection in the Cortex District after the first stage of
development. Photo: Cortex Innovation Community.
Bottom: This view of the same St. Louis intersection in 2016 shows
the completed Commons during The Murmuration Festival, a three-
day event hosted by Cortex so the public could enjoy the site and
explore the intersection of local art, music, science, and technology.
Photo: Cortex Innovation Community. Photograph by Louis Kwok.
Back Cover: The Pritzker Pavilion, designed by renowned architect
Frank Gehry, features large in Chicagos Millennium Park, which was
partially funded by TIF. Photo: Serge Melki/Flickr CC BY 2.0.
Ordering Information
To download a free copy of this
report or to order copies, visit
www.lincolninst.edu and search
by author or title. For additional
information on discounted prices
for bookstores, multiple-copy
orders, and shipping and handling
costs, send your inquiry to
lincolnorders@pssc.com.
EDITOR & PROJECT MANAGER
Emily McKeigue
COPY EDITOR
Allison Bernstein
DESIGN & PRODUCTION
Studio Rainwater
PRINTING
Recycled Paper Printing
113 Brattle Street, Cambridge, MA
02138-3400, USA
P (617) 661-3016 or (800) 526-3873
F (617) 661-7235 or (800) 526-3944
help
@lincolninst.edu
lincolninst.edu
Recycled paper. Printed using
soy-based inks.
ABOUT THIS REPORT
This report explains how tax increment financing (TIF)
districts work, illustrates TIF use with case studies from
around the country, discusses the rationales for using TIF,
describes TIF’s potential benefits and pitfalls, and reviews
a large body of academic work that evaluates TIF’s effects
on economic development. The author also examines
additional academic literature about the impact of TIF on
school districts and other potential unintended side effects.
The report concludes that, although results are mixed, TIF
often fails to meet its primary goal to increase real estate
development and other economic growth. Based on these
findings, the report offers recommendations to make TIF
districts more successful, equitable, and efficient. David
Merriman is an expert in state and local public finance,
business taxation, and urban economic development. He
teaches and performs research in the Department of Public
Administration and the Institute of Government and Public
Affairs at the University of Illinois at Chicago. His research
has been published in many peer review journals, and he is
frequently quoted in local and national news media.
113 Brattle Street, Cambridge, MA
02138-3400, USA
P (617) 661-3016 or (800) 526-3873
F (617) 661-7235 or (800) 526-3944
help
@lincolninst.edu
lincolninst.edu
Copyright © 2018 Lincoln Institute of Land Policy
All rights reserved.
POLICY FOCUS REPORT SERIES
The policy focus report series is published by the
Lincoln Institute of Land Policy to address timely public
policy issues relating to land use, land markets, and
property taxation. Each report is designed to bridge
the gap between theory and practice by combining
research findings, case studies, and contributions from
scholars in a variety of academic disciplines, and from
professional practitioners, local officials, and citizens in
diverse communities.
ISBN 978-1-55844-377-8 (paper)
Policy Focus Report/Code: PF050
ISBN 978-1-55844-378-5 (PDF)
ABOUT THE LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
www.lincolninst.edu
The Lincoln Institute of Land Policy seeks to improve quality of life through
the effective use, taxation, and stewardship of land. A nonprofit, private
operating foundation whose origins date to 1946, the Lincoln Institute
researches and recommends creative approaches to land as a solution to
economic, social, and environmental challenges. Through education, train-
ing, publications, and events, we integrate theory and practice to inform
public policy decisions worldwide. With locations in Cambridge, Mas-
sachusetts; Washington, DC; Phoenix; and Beijing, we organize our work
in seven major areas: Planning and Urban Form, Valuation and Taxation,
International and Institute-Wide Initiatives, Latin America and the Carib-
bean, Peoples Republic of China, the Babbitt Center for Land and Water
Policy, and the Center for Community Investment.
DAVID MERRIMAN
POLICY FOCUS REPORT LINCOLN INSTITUTE OF LAND POLICY
ISBN 978–1–55844–377–8 (paper)
Policy Focus Report/Code PF050
ISBN 978–1–55844–378–5 (PDF)
IMPROVING TAX INCREMENT FINANCING (TIF) FOR ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
DAVID MERRIMAN
ISBN 978-1-55844-377-8
Improving Tax Increment Financing (TIF)
for Economic Development
One of the main responsibilities of local government is to promote economic activity for the benefit of all stakeholders,
including residents and businesses. Tax increment financing (TIF) is one tool that cities can use to support economic
development in a designated area by earmarking property tax revenues from anticipated increases in assessed
property values resulting from investment in that district. Virtually every state allows some form of TIF, which requires
cooperation between government and the private sector.
Yet, the fundamental attributes of TIF are still poorly understood, and its effectiveness is disputed. Many states
do little to track or evaluate the use of TIF. Recent findings show that TIF does little to deliver economic growth and
sometimes simply relocates economic activity that would have occurred elsewhere without TIF. Empirical studies
suggest that communities should use TIF cautiously to avoid diverting increased property tax revenues from overlying
governments, obscuring government financial records, and facilitating unproductive fiscal competition between
neighboring jurisdictions.
Written by an expert and educator in public finance, business taxation, and urban economic development, this report
presents data about TIF usage, explains how it is intended to work, notes its conceptual strengths and limitations,
reviews academic evaluations of its use, and offers the following recommendations for improving its design.
States should track and monitor TIF use.
States should revise statutes to allow counties,
school districts, and other overlying local govern-
ments to opt out of contributing resources to TIF
districts.
State legislators should review their “but for”
TIF requirements to determine whether they
are effective.
Local governments should provide extensive, easily
accessible information about TIF use, revenues, and
expenditures.
Researchers should study, document, and explain the
different outcomes resulting from TIF use in various
geographic areas.
Improving Tax Increment Financing (TIF)
for Economic Development